Advertisement

Journal of International Business Studies

, Volume 40, Issue 9, pp 1432–1454 | Cite as

Down with MNE-centric theories! Market entry and expansion as the bundling of MNE and local assets

  • Jean-François HennartEmail author
Article

Abstract

Both Anderson and Gatignon and the Uppsala internationalization model see the initial mode of foreign market entry and subsequent modes of operation as unilaterally determined by multinational enterprises (MNEs) arbitraging control and risk and increasing their commitment as they gain experience in the target market. OLI and internalization models do recognize that foreign market entry requires the bundling of MNE and complementary local assets, which they call location or country-specific advantages, but implicitly assume that those assets are freely accessible to MNEs. In contrast to both of these MNE-centric views, I explicitly consider the transactional characteristics of complementary local assets and model foreign market entry as the optimal assignment of equity between their owners and MNEs. By looking at the relative efficiency of the different markets in which MNE and complementary local assets are traded, and at how these two categories of assets match, I am able to predict whether equity will be held by MNEs or by local firms, or shared between them, and whether MNEs will enter through greenfields, brownfields, or acquisitions. The bundling model I propose has interesting implications for the evolution of the MNE footprint in host countries, and for the reasons behind the emergence of Dragon MNEs.

Keywords

transaction cost theory internationalization theories and foreign market entry internalization theory agency theory evaluation of current theories multinational corporations (MNCs) and enterprises (MNEs) 

Notes

Acknowledgements

I owe special thanks to Departmental Editor Alain Verbeke for his guidance. I also thank the three anonymous JIBS referees, Alex Eapen, Tom Roehl, and Manuel Bueno for their useful comments. Valuable comments were also received at seminars at Baruch College, City University of New York, the University of Calgary, the University of Sydney, the University of Newcastle, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, Keio Business School, and at the Graduate School of International Strategy at Hitotsubashi University. Financial support from the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science, Osaka City University, and the Japan Foundation is gratefully acknowledged.

References

  1. Ahmed, Z., Mohamad, O., Tan, B., & Johnson, J. 2002. International risk perceptions and mode of entry: A case study of Malaysian multinational firms. Journal of Business Research, 55 (10): 805–814.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Alchian, A., & Allen, W. 1977. Exchange and production: Competition, coordination, and control, (2nd ed.) Belmont: Wadsworth.Google Scholar
  3. Anderson, E., & Coughlan, A. 1987. International market entry and expansion via independent or integrated channels of distribution. Journal of Marketing, 51 (1): 71–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Anderson, E., & Gatignon, H. 1986. Modes of foreign entry: A transaction cost analysis and propositions. Journal of International Business Studies, 17 (3): 1–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Arora, A., & Fosfuri, A. 2000. Wholly owned subsidiary vs technology licensing in the worldwide chemical industry. Journal of International Business Studies, 31 (4): 555–572.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Arora, A., & Gambardella, A. 1998. Evolution of industry structure in the chemical industry. In A. Arora, R. Landau & N. Rosenberg (Eds), Chemicals and long-term economic growth: 379–414. New York: John Wiley.Google Scholar
  7. Arora, A., Fosfuri, A., & Gambardella, A. 2001. Markets for technology and their implications for corporate strategy. Industrial and Corporate Change, 10 (2): 419–451.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Barkema, H., & Vermeulen, F. 1998. International expansion through start-up or acquisition: A learning perspective. Academy of Management Journal, 41 (1): 7–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Bartlett, C., & Ghoshal, S. 1986. Tap your subsidiaries for global reach. Harvard Business Review, 64 (6): 87–94.Google Scholar
  10. Barzel, Y. 1989. Economic analysis of property rights. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  11. Boerner, C., & Macher, J. 2003. Transaction cost economics: An assessment of empirical work in the social sciences. Working Paper, Georgetown University.Google Scholar
  12. Brannen, M., Liker, J., & Fruin, W. M. 1999. Recontextualization and factory-to-factory knowledge transfer from Japan to the United States: The case of NSK. In J. Liker, W. M. Fruin & P. Adler (Eds), Remade in America: 117–153. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  13. Brickly, J., & Dark, F. 1987. The choice of organizational form: The case of franchising. Journal of Financial Economics, 18 (2): 401–420.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Brouthers, K. 1995. The influence of international risk on entry mode strategy. Management International Review, 35 (1): 7–28.Google Scholar
  15. Brouthers, K., & Hennart, J.-F. 2007. Boundaries of the firm: Insights from international entry mode research. Journal of Management, 33 (3): 395–425.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Brouthers, K., Brouthers, L., & Werner, S. 2003. Transaction cost-enhanced entry mode choices and firm performance. Strategic Management Journal, 24 (12): 1239–1248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Buckley, P., & Casson, M. 1976. The future of the multinational enterprise. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Buckley, P., & Casson, M. 1981. The optimal timing of a foreign direct investment. Economic Journal, 91 (361): 75–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Caves, R., & Mehra, S. 1986. Entry of foreign multinationals into US manufacturing industries. In M. Porter (Ed.), Competition in global industries: 449–481. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
  20. Chen, H., Qin, H., Ye, G., & Yin, G. 2001. A technology legend in China. Harvard Business School case 9-701-052.Google Scholar
  21. Chen, S.-F. 2005. Extending internalization theory: A new perspective on international technology transfer and its generalization. Journal of International Business Studies, 36 (2): 231–245.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Chen, S.-F. 2008. The motives for international acquisitions: Capability procurements, strategic considerations, and the role of ownership structures. Journal of International Business Studies, 39 (3): 454–471.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Chen, S.-F., & Hennart, J.-F. 1997. When is original equipment manufacture the most efficient way to source foreign-made products? Paper presented at the Academy of International Business Annual Meetings, Monterrey.Google Scholar
  24. Chi, T. 1994. Trading in strategic resources: Necessary conditions, transaction cost problems, and choice of exchange structure. Strategic Management Journal, 15 (4): 271–290.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Chi, T. 1996. Performance verifiability and output sharing in collaborative ventures. Management Science, 42 (1): 93–109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Das, T. K., & Teng, B. S. 2002. A social exchange theory of strategic alliances. In F. Contractor & P. Lorange (Eds), Cooperative strategies and alliances: 439–460. Amsterdam: Pergamon.Google Scholar
  27. Davidson, W., & McFetridge, D. 1984. International technology transactions and the theory of the firm. Journal of Industrial Economics, 32 (3): 253–264.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Delios, A., & Beamish, P. 1999. Ownership strategy of Japanese firms: Transactional, institutional, and experience influences. Strategic Management Journal, 20 (10): 915–933.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Dunning, J. 1988. The theory of international production. The International Trade Journal, 3 (1): 21–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Dunning, J., & Lundan, S. 2008. Multinational enterprises and the global economy. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  31. Eapen, A. 2007. Essays on international market entry: Strategic alliance governance and product segment entry. PhD Dissertation, Tilburg University.Google Scholar
  32. Erramilli, M., & Rao, C. 1993. Service firms’ international entry mode choice: A modified transaction-cost analysis approach. Journal of Marketing, 57 (3): 19–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Estrin, S., Hughes, K., & Todd, S. 1997. Foreign direct investment in Central and Eastern Europe. London: Pinter.Google Scholar
  34. Eswaran, M., & Kotwal, A. 1985. A theory of contractual structure in agriculture. American Economic Review, 75 (3): 352–367.Google Scholar
  35. Fan, J., Huang, J., Morck, R., & Yeung, B. 2007. Institutional determinants of vertical integration: Evidence from China, Unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
  36. Gatignon, H., & Anderson, E. 1988. The multinational corporation's degree of control over foreign subsidiaries: An empirical test of a transaction cost explanation. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 4 (2): 305–336.Google Scholar
  37. Gaur, A., & Lu, J. 2007. Ownership strategies and survival of foreign subsidiaries: Impacts of institutional distance and experience. Journal of Management, 33 (1): 84–110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Goldstein, A. 2007. Multinational companies from emerging economies. New York: Palgrave.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Gomes-Casseres, B. 1989. Ownership structures of foreign subsidiaries: Theory and evidence. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 11 (1): 1–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Grossman, S., & Hart, O. 1986. The costs and benefits of ownership: A theory of vertical and lateral integration. Journal of Political Economy, 94 (4): 691–719.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Gulati, R., & Singh, H. 1998. The architecture of cooperation: Managing coordination costs and appropriation concerns in strategic alliances. Administrative Science Quarterly, 43 (4): 781–814.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Hart, O., & Moore, J. 1990. Property rights and the nature of the firm. Journal of Political Economy, 98 (6): 1119–1158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Harzing, A. 2001. Acquisitions versus greenfield investments: International strategy and management of entry modes. Strategic Management Journal, 23 (3): 211–227.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Healy, P., & Palepu, K. 1993. International corporate equity acquisitions: Who, where and why? In K. Froot (Ed.), Foreign direct investment: 231–254. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  45. Hennart, J.-F. 1982. A theory of multinational enterprise. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
  46. Hennart, J.-F. 1988. A transaction costs theory of equity joint ventures. Strategic Management Journal, 9 (4): 361–374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Hennart, J.-F. 1989. Can the ‘new forms of investment’ substitute for the ‘old forms’? A transaction costs perspective. Journal of International Business Studies, 20 (2): 211–233.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Hennart, J.-F. 1991. The transaction costs theory of joint ventures: An empirical study of Japanese subsidiaries in the United States. Management Science, 37 (4): 483–497.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Hennart, J.-F. 1993. Explaining the swollen middle: Why most transactions are a mix of ‘market’ and ‘hierarchy’. Organization Science, 4 (4): 529–548.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Hennart, J.-F. 2000. Transaction costs theory and the multinational enterprise. In C. Pitelis & R. Sugden (Eds), The nature of the transnational, (2nd ed.) 72–118. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
  51. Hennart, J.-F., & Park, Y. R. 1993. Greenfield vs. acquisition: The strategy of Japanese investors in the United States. Management Science, 39 (9): 1054–1070.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Hennart, J.-F., & Reddy, S. 1997. The choice between mergers/acquisitions and joint ventures: The case of Japanese investors in the United States. Strategic Management Journal, 18 (1): 1–12.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  53. Ichikawa, T. 2009. Chairman, Toyo Cotton (Japan) Co. personal interview, Osaka, Japan, 23 March.Google Scholar
  54. Ikeda, K. 2007. Deputy general manager, corporate marketing and development division. Sakata Inx, personal interview, Osaka, Japan, 17 May.Google Scholar
  55. Inkpen, A., Sundaram, A., & Rockwood, K. 2000. Cross border acquisitions of US technology assets. California Management Review, 42 (3): 50–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  56. Johanson, J., & Vahlne, J. 1977. The internationalization process of the firm: A model of knowledge development and increasing market commitments. Journal of International Business Studies, 8 (1): 23–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  57. Johanson, J., & Vahlne, J. 1990. The mechanism of internationalization. International Marketing Review, 7 (4): 11–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. Jones, K. 1991. The dilemma of foreign-affiliated companies: Surviving middle age in Japan. In J. Bleeke & D. Ernst (Eds), Collaborating to Compete: 145–163. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
  59. Kay, N. 1999 (Ed.). Collaborative strategies of firms. The Boundaries of the Firm: 177–198. Basingstoke: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  60. Kenney, M. 1999. Transplantation? A comparison of Japanese television assembly plants in Japan and the United States. In J. Liker, W. M. Fruin & P. Adler (Eds), Remade in America: 256–293. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  61. Kenney, M., & Florida, R. 1993. Beyond mass production. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  62. Kilburn, D. 1994. Borden's hopes melt in Japanese market. Advertising Age, 18 July.Google Scholar
  63. Klein, S., Frazier, G., & Roth, V. 1990. A transaction cost analysis model of channel integration in international markets. Journal of Marketing Research, 27 (2): 196–208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  64. Kogut, B. 1988. Joint ventures: Theoretical and empirical perspectives. Strategic Management Journal, 9 (4): 319–332.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  65. Kogut, B., & Singh, H. 1988. The effect of national culture on the choice of entry mode. Journal of International Business Studies, 19 (3): 411–432.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  66. Kreps, D. 1990. A course in microeconomic theory. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  67. Levin, R., Klevorick, R., Nelson, R., & Winter, S. 1987. Appropriating the results from industrial research and development. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 18 (3): 783–820.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  68. Liker, J., Fruin, W. M., & Adler, P. 1999. Bringing Japanese management systems to the United States: Transplantation or transformation? In J. Liker, W. M. Fruin & P. Adler (Eds), Remade in America: 3–35. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  69. Marinov, M., & Marinova, S. 1998. Investor strategy development and adaptation: The case of Interbrew. European Management Journal, 16 (4): 400–411.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  70. Mathews, J. 2002. Competitive advantages of the latecomer firm: A resource-based account of industrial catch-up strategies. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 19 (4): 467–488.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  71. Mathews, J. 2006. Dragon multinationals: New players in 21st century globalization. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 23 (1): 5–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  72. Meyer, K., & Estrin, S. 2001. Brownfield entry in emerging markets. Journal of International Business Studies, 32 (3): 575–584.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  73. Meyer, K., & Møller, I. 1998. Managing deep restructuring: Danish experiences in Eastern Germany. European Management Journal, 16 (4): 411–421.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  74. Millington, A., & Bayliss, B. 1990. The process of internationalization: UK companies in the EC. Management International Review, 30 (2): 151–161.Google Scholar
  75. Morck, R., Yeung, B., & Zhao, M. 2008. Perspectives on China's outward foreign direct investment. Journal of International Business Studies, 39 (3): 337–350.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  76. Narula, R. 2006. Globalization, new ecologies, new zoologies, and the purported death of the eclectic paradigm. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 23 (2): 143–151.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  77. Oman, C. 1984. New forms of international investment in developing countries. Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
  78. Ono, Y. 1991. Corporate divorce, Japanese style. The Globe and Mail, 23 February.Google Scholar
  79. Oxley, J. 1997. Appropriability hazards and governance in strategic alliances: A transaction cost approach. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 13 (2): 387–409.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  80. Padmanabhan, P., & Cho, K. 1996. Ownership strategy for a foreign affiliate: An empirical investigation of Japanese firms. Management International Review, 36 (1): 45–65.Google Scholar
  81. Padmanabhan, P., & Cho, K. 1999. Decision specific experience in foreign ownership and establishment strategies: Evidence from Japanese firms. Journal of International Business Studies, 30 (1): 25–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  82. Pan, Y. 2005. Lenovo: Countering the Dell challenge. Asia Case Research Center case 905-020-1.Google Scholar
  83. Pedersen, T., & Thomsen, S. 1997. European patterns of corporate ownership: A twelve-country study. Journal of International Business Studies, 28 (4): 759–778.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  84. Rugman, A. 1981. Inside the multinational: The economics of internal markets. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
  85. Rugman, A., & Collinson, S. 2006. International business, (4th ed.) Harlow: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
  86. Rugman, A., & Verbeke, A. 1990. Global corporate strategy and trade policy. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
  87. Rui, H., & Yip, G. 2008. Foreign acquisitions by Chinese firms: A strategic intent perspective. Journal of World Business, 43 (2): 213–226.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  88. Sanchez-Peinado, E., & Pla-Barber, J. 2006. A multidimensional concept of uncertainty and its influence on the entry mode choice: An empirical analysis in the service sector. International Business Review, 15 (3): 215–232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  89. Silver, M. 1984. Enterprise and the scope of the firm. Oxford: Martin Robertson.Google Scholar
  90. Slangen, A., & Hennart, J. F. 2007. Greenfield or acquisition entry: A review of the empirical foreign establishment mode literature. Journal of International Management, 13 (4): 404–429.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  91. Teece, D. 1986. Profiting from technological innovation: Implications for integration, collaboration, and public policy. Research Policy, 15 (6): 285–305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  92. Verbeke, A. 2009. International business strategy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  93. Vermeulen, F., & Barkema, H. 2001. Learning through acquisitions. Academy of Management Journal, 44 (3): 457–476.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  94. Vernon, R. 1971. Sovereignty at bay. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
  95. Wei, Y., Liu, B., & Liu, X. 2005. Entry modes of foreign direct investment in China: A multinomial logit approach. Journal of Business Research, 58 (11): 1495–1505.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  96. Williamson, O. 1985. The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
  97. Williamson, O. 1991. Comparative economic organization: The analysis of discrete structural alternatives. Administrative Science Quarterly, 36 (2): 269–296.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  98. Williamson, O. 1996. Economic organization: The case for candor. Academy of Management Review, 21 (1): 48–57.Google Scholar
  99. Wright, M., Filatotchev, I., Hoskisson, R., & Peng, M. 2005. Strategy research in emerging economies. Journal of Management Studies, 42 (1): 1–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  100. Xie, W., & White, S. 2004. Sequential learning in a Chinese spin-off: The case of Lenovo Group Limited. R&D Management, 34 (4): 407–422.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  101. Yeung, B., & Mirus, R. 1989. On the mode of international expansion: The role of agency costs in an expanded framework, Unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
  102. Yuasa, K. 1990. Meiji Milk, Borden to end tie. Japan Economic Journal, 23 June.Google Scholar
  103. Zeng, M., & Williamson, P. 2007. Dragons at your door: How Chinese cost innovation is disrupting global competition. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Academy of International Business 2009

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.CentER and Department of Organization and StrategyTilburg UniversityThe Netherlands

Personalised recommendations