IMF Economic Review

, Volume 63, Issue 1, pp 71–109 | Cite as

Aggregate Supply in the United States: Recent Developments and Implications for the Conduct of Monetary Policy

  • Dave Reifschneider
  • William Wascher
  • David Wilcox
Article

Abstract

The recent financial crisis and ensuing recession appear to have put the productive capacity of the economy on a lower and shallower trajectory than the one that seemed to be in place prior to 2007. Using a version of an unobserved components model introduced by Fleischman and Roberts, we estimate that potential GDP in late 2014 was about 7 percent below the trajectory it appeared to be on prior to 2007. We argue that a significant portion of the recent damage to the supply side of the economy plausibly was endogenous to the weakness in aggregate demand. Endogeneity of supply with respect to demand provides a strong motivation for a vigorous policy response to a weakening in aggregate demand, and we present optimal-control simulations showing how monetary policy might respond to such endogeneity in the absence of other considerations. We then discuss how other considerations—such as increased risks of financial instability or inflation instability—could cause policymakers to exercise restraint in their response to cyclical weakness.

JEL Classifications

E230 E320 E520 

Supplementary material

41308_2015_BFimfer20151_MOESM1_ESM.zip (7.5 mb)
Supplementary Information

References

  1. Aaronson, Stephanie, Bruce Fallick, Andrew Figura, Jonathan Pingle, and William Wascher, 2006, “The Recent Decline in the Labor Force Participation Rate and Its Implications for Potential Labor Supply,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity Vol. 2006, No. 1, pp. 69–154.Google Scholar
  2. Aaronson, Stephanie, Tomaz Cajner, Bruce Fallick, Felix Galbis-Reig, Christopher Smith, and William Wascher, 2014, “Labor Force Participation: Recent Developments and Future Prospects,” Federal Reserve Board Finance and Economics Discussion Paper No. 2014-64 (September).Google Scholar
  3. Adolfson, Malin, Stefan Laseen, Jesper Linde, and Lars E. O. Svensson, 2011, “Optimal Monetary Policy in an Operational Medium-Sized DSGE Model,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 43, No. 7, pp. 1287–1331.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Aghion, Philippe, Philippe Askenazy, Nicolas Berman, Gilbert Cette and Laurent Eymard, 2012, “Credit Constraints and the Cyclicality of R&D Investment: Evidence from France,” Journal of the European Economic Association, Vol. 10, No. 5, pp. 1001–1024.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Ascari, Guido and Argia M. Sbordone, 2013, The Macroeconomics of Trend Inflation, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports No. 628 (August).Google Scholar
  6. Ball, Laurence, 1999, “Aggregate Demand and Long-Run Unemployment,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 1999, No. 2, pp. 189–251.Google Scholar
  7. Barlevy, Gadi, 2007, “On the Cyclicality of Research and Development,” American Economic Review, Vol. 97, No. 4, pp. 1131–1164.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Barro, Robert J. and David B. Gordon, 1983, “A Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in a Natural-Rate Model,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 91, No. 4, pp. 589–610.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Basistha, Arabinda and Richard Startz, 2008, “Measuring the NAIRU with Reduced Uncertainty: A Muliple-Indicator Common-Cycle Approach,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 90, No. 4, pp. 805–811.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Basu, Susanto and John G. Fernald, 2009, “What Do We Know (and Not Know) About Potential Output?,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review Vol. 91, No. 4, 187–214.Google Scholar
  11. Blanchard, Olivier J. and Lawrence H. Summers, 1986, “Hysteresis and the European Unemployment Problem,” NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Vol. 1, pp. 15–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Blanchard, Olivier J. and Danny Quah, 1989, “The Dynamic Effects of Aggregate Demand and Supply Disturbances,” American Economic Review, Vol. 79, No. 4, pp. 655–673.Google Scholar
  13. Blanchard, Olivier J., 2003, “Monetary Policy and Unemployment,” remarks at Monetary Policy and the Labor Market: A Conference in Honor of James Tobin, New School, New York, November 2002.Google Scholar
  14. Brayton, Flint, Thomas Laubach, and David Reifschneider, 2014, “Optimal-Control Monetary Policy in the FRB/US Model,” Federal Reserve Board Notes (November 21, 2014).Google Scholar
  15. Brayton, Flint et al. 1997, “The Role of Expectations in the FRB/US Macroeconomic Model,” Federal Reserve Bulletin, Vol. 83 (April), pp. 43–81.Google Scholar
  16. Cerra, Valerie and Sweta Chaman Saxena, 2008, “Growth Dynamics: The Myth of Economic Recovery,” American Economic Review, Vol. 98, No. 1, pp. 439–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Clark, Peter K., 1987, “The Cyclical Component of U.S. Economic Activity,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 102, No. 4, pp. 797–814.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Clark, Todd, 2011, “Real-Time Density Forecasts from Bayesian Vector Autoregressions with Stochastic Volatility,” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, Vol. 29, No. 3, pp. 327–341.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Comin, Diego and Mark Gertler, 2006, “Medium-Term Business Cycles,” American Economic Review, Vol. 96, No. 3, pp. 523–551.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Congressional Budget Office. 2001, “CBO’s Method for Estimating Potential Output: An Update,” Congress of the United States, Washington, D.C. (August).Google Scholar
  21. Congressional Budget Office. 2012, “What Accounts for the Slow Growth of the Economy After the Recession?” Congress of the United States, Washington, D.C. (November).Google Scholar
  22. Del Negro, Marco, Marc P. Giannoni, and Frank Schorfheide, 2013, Inflation in the Great Recession and New Keynesian Models, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports No. 618 (May).Google Scholar
  23. De Masi, P., 1997, “IMF Estimates of Potential Output: Theory and Practice,” Staff Studies for the World Economic Outlook, December.Google Scholar
  24. Dornbush, Rudiger and Stanley Fischer, 1978, Macroeconomics. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
  25. Erceg, Christopher J. and Andrew T. Levin, 2013, “Labor Force Participation and Monetary Policy in the Wake of the Great Recession,” IMF working paper No. 13-245.Google Scholar
  26. European Central Bank. 2000, “Potential Output and Output Gaps,” ECB Monthly Bulletin Vol. (October), pp. 37–48.Google Scholar
  27. European Central Bank. 2011, “Trends in Potential Output,” ECB Monthly Bulletin, Vol. (February), 73–85.Google Scholar
  28. Fernald, John G., 2012, “Productivity and Potential Output Before, During and After the Great Recession,” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2012-18.Google Scholar
  29. Fleischman, Charles A. and John M. Roberts, 2011, “From Many Series, One Cycle: Improved Estimates of the Business Cycle from a Multivariate Unobserved Components Model,” Federal Reserve Board Finance and Economics Discussion Series No. 2011-46.Google Scholar
  30. Frey, William, 2014, “US Population Growth and Migration Sputter, Yet Again,” Brookings (January 24).Google Scholar
  31. Gordon, Robert J., 2003, “Exploding Productivity Growth: Context, Causes, and Implications,” Brookings Papers of Economic Activity, Vol. 2003, No. 2, pp. 207-279.Google Scholar
  32. Gordon, Robert J., 2012, “Is U.S. Economic Growth Over? Faltering Innovation Confronts the Six Headwinds,” NBER Working Paper No. 18315.Google Scholar
  33. Haltiwanger, John, Ron Jarmin, and Javier Miranda, 2013, “Where have all the Young Firms Gone?,” Kaufman Foundation, May.Google Scholar
  34. Ikeda, Daisuke and Takushi Kurozumi, 2014, “Post-Crisis Slow Recovery and Monetary Policy,” Bank of Japan Discussion Paper No. 2014-E-16.Google Scholar
  35. Kienzler, Daniel and Kai D. Schmid, 2013, “Monetary Policy and Hysteresis in Potential Output,” University of Tubingen Working Papers in Economics and Finance, No. 55.Google Scholar
  36. Kiley, Michael T., 2007, “A Quantitative Comparison of Sticky-Price and Sticky-Information Models of Price Setting,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 39, No. s1, pp. 101–125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Kiley, Michael T., 2012, “Output Gaps,” Federal Reserve Board Finance and Economic Discussion Series 2010-27.Google Scholar
  38. Kroft, Kory, Fabian Lange, and Matthew J. Notowidigdo, 2013, “Duration Dependence and Labor Market Conditions: Evidence from a Field Experiment,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 128, No. 3, pp. 1123–1167.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Kuttner, Kenneth N., 1994, “Estimating Potential Output as a Latent Variable,” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, Vol. 12, No. 3, pp. 361–368.Google Scholar
  40. Kuttner, Kenneth N. and Adam S. Posen, 2001, “The Great Recession: Lessons for Macroeconomic Policy from Japan,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 2001, No. 2, pp. 93–160.Google Scholar
  41. Laforte, Jean-Philippe, 2007, “Pricing Models: A Bayesian DSGE Approach for the U.S. Economy,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 39, No. s1, pp. 127–154.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Lucas Jr. Robert E., 1972, “Econometric Testing of the Natural Rate Hypothesis,” The Econometrics of Price Determination, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.Google Scholar
  43. Martin, Robert and Beth Anne Wilson, 2013, “Potential Output and Recessions: Are We Fooling Ourselves,” Federal Reserve Board. Notes (November 12, 2014).Google Scholar
  44. Nalewaik, Jeremy J., 2010, “The Income- and Expenditure-Side Estimates of U.S. Output Growth,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity,, Vol. 2010, No. 1, pp. 71–106.Google Scholar
  45. Neiss, Katherine S. and Edward Nelson, 2003, “The Real Interest Rate Gap as an Inflation Indicator,” Macroeconomic Dynamics, Vol. 7, No. 2, pp. 239–262.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  46. Okun, Arthur M., 1973, “Upward Mobility in a High-Pressure Economy,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 1973, No. 1, pp. 207–252.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Poole, William, 1971, “Alternative Paths to a Stable Full-Employment Economy,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 1973, No. 3, pp. 579–606.Google Scholar
  48. Reinhart, Carmin M. and Kenneth S. Rogoff, 2010, This Time is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  49. Shleifer, Andrei, 1986, “Implementation Cycles,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 94, No. 6, pp. 1163–1190.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Stockhammer, Englebert and Simon Sturn, 2012, “The Impact of Monetary Policy on Unemployment Hysteresis,” Applied Economics, Vol. 44, No. 21, pp. 2743–2756.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Svensson, Lars E. O., 2003, “What is Wrong with Taylor Rules? Using Judgment in Monetary Policy through Targeting Rules,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 41, No. 2, pp. 426–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Svensson, Lars E. O., 2005, “Monetary Policy with Judgment: Forecast Targeting,” International Journal of Central Banking, Vol. 1, No. 1, pp. 1–54.Google Scholar
  53. Svensson, Lars E. O. and Robert Tetlow, 2005, “Optimal Policy Projections,” International Journal of Central Banking, Vol. 1, No. 3, pp. 177–207.Google Scholar
  54. Taylor, John B., 1999, “A Historical Analysis of Monetary Policy Rules,” in Monetary Policy Rules, ed. by John B. Taylor, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 319–341.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  55. Woodford, Michael, 2003, Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© International Monetary Fund 2015

Authors and Affiliations

  • Dave Reifschneider
  • William Wascher
  • David Wilcox

There are no affiliations available

Personalised recommendations