Advertisement

BioSocieties

, Volume 6, Issue 1, pp 34–50 | Cite as

Demythologizing the high costs of pharmaceutical research

  • Donald W LightEmail author
  • Rebecca Warburton
Original Article

Abstract

It is widely claimed that research to discover and develop new pharmaceuticals entails high costs and high risks. High research and development (R&D) costs influence many decisions and policy discussions about how to reduce global health disparities, how much companies can afford to discount prices for lower- and middle-income countries, and how to design innovative incentives to advance research on diseases of the poor. High estimated costs also affect strategies for getting new medicines to the world's poor, such as the advanced market commitment, which built high estimates into its inflated size and prices. This article takes apart the most detailed and authoritative study of R&D costs in order to show how high estimates have been constructed by industry-supported economists, and to show how much lower actual costs may be. Besides serving as an object lesson in the construction of ‘facts’, this analysis provides reason to believe that R&D costs need not be such an insuperable obstacle to the development of better medicines. The deeper problem is that current incentives reward companies to develop mainly new medicines of little advantage and compete for market share at high prices, rather than to develop clinically superior medicines with public funding so that prices could be much lower and risks to companies lower as well.

Keywords

pharmaceutical research costs myths neglected diseases AMC (Advance Market Commitment) 

References

  1. Adamini, S., Maarse, H., Versluis, E. and Light, D.W. (2009) Policy making on data exclusivity in the European Union: From industrial interests to legal realities. Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law 34: 979–1010.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Andrews, E.L. (2005) Hitting the tax-break jackpot. The New York Times, 1 February: C1–C2.Google Scholar
  3. Angell, M. (2004) The Truth About the Drug Companies: How They Deceive Us and What to Do About It. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
  4. Barton, J. and Emanuel, E. (2005) The patent-based pharmaceutical development process: Rationale, problems, and potential reforms. Journal of American Medical Association 294: 2075–2082.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Berenson, A. (2005) Tax break gives huge benefits to drugmakers. New York Times, 8 May.Google Scholar
  6. Boston Consulting Group. (2001) A Revolution in R&D. Boston, MA: Boston Consulting Group.Google Scholar
  7. Butler, D. (2010) Cash crisis looms for vaccine drive. Nature 464: 338.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Canadian Coordinating Office for Health Technology Assessment. (1997) Guidelines for Economic Evaluation of Pharmaceuticals, 2nd Edition. Ottawa, Canada: Canadian Coordinating Office for Health Technology Assessment.Google Scholar
  9. Carpenter, D., Zucker, E.J. and Avorn, J. (2008) Drug-review deadlines and safety problems. New England Journal of Medicine 358: 1354–1361, (1359: 1396–1398).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. DiMasi, J.A., Hansen, R.W. and Grabowski, H. (2003a) The price of innovation: New estimates of drug development costs. Journal of Health Economics 22: 151–185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. DiMasi, J.A., Hansen, R.W. and Grabowski, H.G. (2003b) The price of innovation: New estimates of drug development costs, Appendix B, pp. 1–6. Tufts University (unpublished).Google Scholar
  12. DiMasi, J.A., Hansen, R.W., Grabowski, H.G. and Lasagna, L. (1991) Cost of innovation in the pharmaceutical industry. Journal of Health Economics 10: 107–142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. EFPIA. (2010) The Pharmaceutical Industry in Figures. Brussels, Belgium: European Federation of Pharmaceutical Industries and Associations.Google Scholar
  14. Engelberg, A.B. (1982) Patent term extension: An overreaching solution to a nonexistent problem. Health Affairs 1 (2): 34–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. European Commission for Competition. (28 November 2008) Pharmaceutical Sector Inquiry – Preliminary Report. Brussels, Belgium: European Commission for Competition.Google Scholar
  16. Farlow, A. (2005) Accelerating the innovation of vaccines. Innovation Strategy Today 1 (2): 66–202.Google Scholar
  17. Fisher, J.A. (2009) Medical Research for Hire: the Political Economy of Pharmaceutical Clinical Trials. New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press.Google Scholar
  18. Frew, S.E., Kettler, H.E. and Singer, P.A. (2008) The Indian and Chinese health biotechnology industries: Potential champions of global health? Health Affairs 27 (4): 1029–1041.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. General Accounting Office. (2003) Technology Transfer: NIH-Private Sector Partnership in the Development of Taxol, (No. GAO-03-829). Washington DC: General Accounting Office.Google Scholar
  20. Goozner, M. (2004) The $800 Million Pill: The Truth Behind the Cost of New Drugs. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
  21. Grabowski, H. (ed.) (1976) Drug Regulation and Innovation: Empirical Evidence and Policy Options. Washington DC: American Enterprise Institute.Google Scholar
  22. Grabowski, H.G. (1978) Drug Regulation and Innovation. Washington DC: American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research.Google Scholar
  23. Hansen, R.W. (1979) The pharmaceutical development process: Estimates of current development costs and times and the effects of regulatory changes. In: R.I. Chien (ed.) Issues in Pharmaceutical Economics. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, pp. 151–187.Google Scholar
  24. Harris, G. (2001) Health costs of developing new medicine swelled to $802 million, research study reports. Wall Street Journal; http://www.globalaging.org/health/world/costnewmedicines.htm, accessed November 2010.
  25. Keyhani, S., Diener-West, M. and Powe, N. (2006) Are development times for pharmaceuticals increasing or decreasing? Health Affairs 25 (2): 461–468.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Kremer, M. and Glennerster, R. (2004) Strong Medicine: Creating Incentives for Pharmaceutical Research on Neglected Diseases. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  27. Le Fanu, J. (1999) The Rise and Fall of Modern Medicine. New York: Carroll & Graf Publishers.Google Scholar
  28. Light, D.W. (2006) Basic research funds to discover important new drugs: Who contributes how much? In: M.A. Burke (ed.) Monitoring the Financial Flows for Health Research 2005: Behind the Global Numbers. Geneva, Switzerland: Global Forum for Health Research, pp. 27–43.Google Scholar
  29. Light, D.W. (2007) Is G8 putting profits before the world's poorest children? The Lancet 370: 297–298.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Light, D.W. (2009) Advanced Market Commitments: Current Realities and Alternate Approaches. Amsterdam, the Netherlands: HAI Europe/Medico International Publication.Google Scholar
  31. Light, D.W. (ed.) (2010) The Risk of Prescription Drugs. New York: Columbia University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Light, D.W., Andrus, J. and Warburton, R. (2009) Estimated costs of research and development of rotavirus vaccines. Vaccine 27: 6627–6633.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Light, D.W. and Lexchin, J. (2005) Foreign free riders and the high price of US medicines. BMJ 331: 958–960.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Love, J. (2003) Evidence Regarding Research and Development Investments in Innovative and Non-Innovative Medicines. Washington DC: Consumer Project on Technology.Google Scholar
  35. McGoey, L. (2009) Pharmaceutical controversies and the performative value of uncertainty. Science as Culture 18: 151–164.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Mitsuya, H., Winhold, K., Yarchoan, R., Bolognesi, D. and Broder, S. (1989) Credit government scientists with developing anti-AIDS drugs (letter). New York Times.Google Scholar
  37. Moran, M. (2005) A breakthrough in R&D for neglected diseases: New ways to get the drugs we need. PLoS Medicine 2 (9): e302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Moran, M . et al (2007) The Malaria Product Pipeline: Planning for the Future. Sydney, Australia: The George Institute for International Health.Google Scholar
  39. Morgan, S.G . et al (2005) ‘Breakthrough’ drugs and growth in expenditure on prescription drugs in Canada. BMJ 331: 815–816.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. National Institute for Health Care Management. (2000) Prescription Drugs and Intellectual Property Protection. Washington DC: National Institute for Health Care Management.Google Scholar
  41. National Science Foundation. (2003) Research and Development in Industry: 2000. Arlington, VA: National Science Foundation, Division of Science Resources Statistics.Google Scholar
  42. Olson, M.K. (2004) Are novel drugs more risky for patients than less novel drugs? Journal of Health Economics 23: 1135–1158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Patented Medicine Prices Review Board. (2002) A Comparison of Pharmaceutical Research and Development Spending, (No. PMPRB Study Series S-0217). Ottawa, Canada: PMPRB.Google Scholar
  44. Pharmaceutical R&D Policy Project. (2005) The New Landscape of Neglected Disease Drug Development. London: The Wellcome Trust and London School of Economics and Political Science.Google Scholar
  45. Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers of America. (2002) Pharmaceutical Industry Profile 2002. Washington DC: Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers of America.Google Scholar
  46. PhRMA. (2009) Pharmaceutical Industry Profile 2009. Washington DC: Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers of America.Google Scholar
  47. Plahte, J. (2005) Tiered pricing of vaccines: A win-win-win situation, not a subsidy. The Lancet Infectious Diseases 5 (1): 58–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Public Citizen. (2001) Rx R&D Myths: The Case Against the Drug Industry's R&D ‘Scare Card’. Washington DC: Public Citizen.Google Scholar
  49. Russell, K.B., Gold, M.R., Siegel, J.E., Daniels, N. and Weinstein, M.C. (1996) The role of cost-effectiveness analysis in health and medicine: Panel on cost-effectivess in health and medicine. Journal of American Medical Association 276: 1172–1177.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Tax Policy Center. (2002) Marginal rates of the Federal Corporation Income Tax, 1942–2002. Washington DC: Tax Policy Center.Google Scholar
  51. United States Office of Management and Budget. (2003) Guidelines and Discount Rates for Benefit-Cost Analysis of Federal Programs. Washington DC: United States Office of Management and Budget.Google Scholar
  52. US Food and Drug Administration. (2004) NDAs Approved in Calendar Years1990–2003 by Therapeutic Potential and Chemical Types. Washington DC: U.S. Food and Drug Administration.Google Scholar
  53. US Office of Technology Assessment. (1993) Pharmaceutical R&D: Costs, Risks and Rewards, (No. NTIS #PB93-163376). Washington DC: Office of Technology Assessment.Google Scholar
  54. Wardell, W.M. and Lasagna, L. (eds.) (1975) Regulation and Drug Development. Washington DC: American Enterprise Institute.Google Scholar
  55. Waxman, H., Durbin, R.J. and Kennedy, E.M. (2006) New GAO Analysis of Drug Development Refutes Industry Myths. Washington DC: U.S. Congress.Google Scholar
  56. Weinstein, M.C., Siegel, J.E., Gold, M.R., Kamlet, M.S. and Russell, L.B. (1996) Recommendations of the panel on cost-effectiveness in health and medicine. Journal of American Medical Association 276: 1253–1258.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© The London School of Economics and Political Science 2011

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Program in Human BiologyStanford UniversityStanfordCAUSA
  2. 2.University of Medicine and Dentistry of New JerseyNJUSA
  3. 3.School of Public Administration, University of VictoriaVictoriaCanada

Personalised recommendations