Skip to main content

Empirical Analysis of Indirect Network Effects in the Market for Personal Digital Assistants

Abstract

We present a framework to measure empirically the size of indirect network effects in high-technology markets with competing incompatible technology standards. These indirect network effects arise due to inter-dependence in demand for hardware and compatible software. By modeling the joint determination of hardware sales and software availability in the market, we are able to describe the nature of demand inter-dependence and to measure the size of the indirect network effects. We apply the model to price and sales data from the industry for personal digital assistants (PDAs) along with the availability of software titles compatible with each PDA hardware standard. Our empirical results indicate significant indirect network effects. By July 2002, the network effect explains roughly 22% of the log-odds ratio of the sales of all Palm O/S compatible PDA-s to Microsoft O/S compatible PDA-s, where the remaining 78% reflects price and model features. We also use our model estimates to study the growth of the installed bases of Palm and Microsoft PDA hardware, with and without the availability of compatible third party software. We find that lack of third party software negatively impacts the evolution of the installed hardware bases of both formats. These results suggest PDA hardware firms would benefit from investing resources in increasing the provision of software for their products. We then compare the benefits of investments in software with investments in the quality of hardware technology. This exercise helps disentangle the potential for incremental hardware sales due to hardware quality improvement from that of positive feedback due to market software provision.

This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.

References

  • Anderson, S., A. De Palma, and J.F. Thisse. (1989). “Demand for Differentiated Products, Discrete Choice Models, and the Characteristics Approach”, Review of Economic Studies 56, 21-35.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee, A. (1992). “A Simple Model of Herd Behavior”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 107, 797-817.

    Google Scholar 

  • Basu, A., T. Mazumdar, and S.P. Raj. (2003). “Indirect Network Externality Effects on Product Attributes”, 2002, Marketing Science 22(2), 209-221.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bayus, Barry L., Sanjay Jain, and Ambar G. Rao. (1997). “Too Little too Early: Introduction Timing and New Product Performance in the Personal Digital Industry”, Journal of Marketing Research 34, 50-63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besanko, D., S. Gupta, and D. Jain. (1998). “Logit Demand Estimation under Competitive Pricing Behavior: An Equilibrium Framework”, Management Science 44(11), 1533-1547.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berry, S. (1994). “Estimating Discrete Choice Models of Product Differentiation”, Rand Journal of Economics 25(2), 242-261.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berry, S., J. Levinsohn, and A. Pakes. (1995). “Automobile Prices in Market Equilibrium”, Econometrica 60(4), 841-890.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bikhchandani, S., D. Hirshleifer, and I. Welch. (1998). “Learning from the Behavior of others: Conformity, Fads, and Informational Cascades”, Journal of Economic Perspectives 12, 151-170.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bresnahan, T. (2002). “The Economics of the Microsoft Case”, Working Paper, Stanford University.

  • Brynjolfsson, E. and C. Kemerer. (1996). “Network Externalities in Microcomputer Software: An Econometric Analysis of the Spreadsheet Market”, Management Science 42(12), 1627-2647.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caminal, P. and Xavier Vives. (1996). “Why Market Shares Matter: An Information Based Theory”, Rand Journal of Economics 27(2), 221-239.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cardell, N.S. (1997). “Variance Component Structures for the Extreme Value and Logistic Distributions with Applications to Models of Heterogeneity”, Econometric Theory 13, 185-213.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chou, C.F. and O. Shy. (1996). “Do Consumers Gain or Lose When More People Buy the Same Brand?” European Journal of Political Economy 12, 309-330.

    Google Scholar 

  • Church, J. and N. Gandal. (1992). “Network Effects, Software Provision, and Standardization”, Journal of Industrial Economics 40, 85-104.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A. and J. Stiglitz. (1977). “Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity”, American Economic Review 67, 297-308.

    Google Scholar 

  • Economides, N. and Charles Himmelberg. (1995). “Critical Mass and Network Size with Applications to the US Fax Market”, Discussion Paper no. EC-95-11, Stern School of Business, N.Y.U.

  • Gandal, N. (1994). “Hedonic Price Indexes for Spreadsheets and an Empirical Test for Network Externalities”, Rand Journal of Economics 25(1), 160-170.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gandal, N., M. Kende, and R. Rob. (2000). “The Dynamics of Technological Adoption in Hardware/Software Systems: The Case of Compact Disc Players”, Rand Journal of Economics 31-1.

  • Gupta, S., D. Jain, and M.S. Sawhney. (1999). “Modeling the Evolution of Markets with Indirect Network Externalities: An Application to Digital Television”, Marketing Science 18(3), 396-416.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karaca-Mandic, P. (2003). “Network Effects in Technology Adoption: The Case of DVD Players”, Working Paper, University of California, Berkeley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ohashi, H. (2003). “The Role of Network Externalities in the US VCR Market; 1978–86”, Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 12(4), Winter.

  • Pakes, A. and D. Pollard. (1989). “Simulation and the Asymptotics of Optimization Estimators”, Econometrica 57, 1027-1057.

    Google Scholar 

  • Park, S. (2002a). “Quantitative Analysis of Network Externalities in Competing Technologies: The VCR Case”, Working Paper, SUNY at Stony Brook.

  • Park, S. (2002b). “Linear Network Benefit Function in the Presence of Indirect Network Externalities”, Working Paper, SUNY at Stony Brook.

  • Rysman, M. (2003). “Competition Between Networks: A Study of the Market for Yellow Pages”, Review of Economic Studies, forthcoming.

  • Saloner, G. and A. Shepard. (1995). “Adoption of Technologies with Network Externalities: An Empirical Examination of the Adoption of Automated Teller Machines”, Rand Journal of Economics 26(3), 479-501.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shankar, V. and B. Bayus. (2003). “Network Effects and Competition: An Empirical Analysis of the Video Game Industry”, 2002, Strategic Management Journal, forthcoming.

  • Shapiro, C. and Hal R. Varian. (1999). “Information Rules: A Strategic Guide to the Network Economy”, Harvard Business School Press.

  • Song, I. and P.K. Chintagunta. (2003), “A Micromodel of New Product Adoption with Heterogeneous and Forward-Looking Consumers: Application to the Digital Camera Category”, Quantitative Marketing and Economics 1(4), 371-407.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spence, M. (1976). “Product Selection, Fixed Costs and Monopolistic Competition”, Review of Economic Studies 43, 217-235.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and Permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Nair, H., Chintagunta, P. & Dubé, JP. Empirical Analysis of Indirect Network Effects in the Market for Personal Digital Assistants. Quantitative Marketing and Economics 2, 23–58 (2004). https://doi.org/10.1023/B:QMEC.0000017034.98302.44

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1023/B:QMEC.0000017034.98302.44

  • high-technology products
  • indirect network effects
  • positive feedback
  • endogeneity