Skip to main content
Log in

Public Goods Theory from Eighteenth Century Political Philosophy to Twentieth Century Economics

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Some scholars have studiedMancur Olson's legacy by investigating theeffects of his research on the socialsciences (McLean, 2000). Others havescrutinized the logical and empiricalimplications of his theories (Sandler,1992; Marsh, 1976; Chamberlin, 1974;Frohlich and Oppenheimer, 1970). A thirdgroup have quietly claimed that hisgreatest work, The logic of collectiveaction, was little more than apopularization of earlier ideas (Dowding,1997; Chamberlain, 1966). This paperattempts to exonerate Olson of the latterclaim by reviewing the major contributionsto collective action theory before his timeand comparing them to The logic ofcollective action.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Alt, J. (1999). Thoughts on Mancur Olson's contribution to political science. Public Choice 98: 1–4.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bailyn, B. (Ed.) (1993). The debate on the constitution. 2 vols. New York: Library of America.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R.E. (1989). The political economy of trade policy. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 3: 119–135.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W.J. ([1952] 1969). Welfare economics and the theory of the state. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowen, H. (1943). The interpretation of voting in the allocation of economic resources. Quarterly Journal of Economics 58: 27–48.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brand, D.R. (1983). corporatism, the NRA, and the oil Industry. Political Science Quarterly 98: 99–118.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1965). An economic theory of clubs. Econonmica 35 (125): 1–14.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chamberlain, N. (1966). The logic of collective action (book review). American Economic Review 56: 603–605.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chamberlin, J. (1974). Provision of collective goods as a function of group size. American Political Science Review 68: 707–716.

    Google Scholar 

  • Darden, L. (1991). Theory change in science: Strategies from Mendelian genetics. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dougherty, K.L. (2001). Collective action under the Articles of Confederation. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dougherty, K.L. (2003). Madison's theory of public goods. In S. Kernell (Ed.), James Madison: the theory and practice of government. Stanford: Stanford University Press (forthcoming).

    Google Scholar 

  • Dowding, K. (1997). Olson, Mancur. In N. Parker and S. Sim (Eds.), The A–Z guide to modern social and political theorists, 270–273. New York: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper and Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Esteban, J. and Ray, D. (2001). Collective action and the group size paradox. American Political Science Review 95: 663–672.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frohlich, N. and Oppenheimer, J. (1970). I get by with a little help from my friends. Journal of World Politics 23: 104–120.

    Google Scholar 

  • Head, J. (1962). Public goods and public policy. Public Finance 27:197–219.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hume, D. ([1739–40] 1978). A treatise of human nature. In L.A. Selby-Bigge (Ed.). Oxford, UK: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hutchinson, W.T., Rachal, W. and Schneider, J. (Eds.) (1962-). The papers of James Madison.Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M. (Ed.) (1976). The documentary history of the ratification of the Constitution. Madison: State Historical Society of Wisconsin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuhn, T. (1970). The structure of scientific revolutions, second edition. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindahl, E. ([1919] 1967). Just taxation – a positive solution. In R. Musgrave and A. Peacock (Eds.), Classics in the theory of public finance, 168–176. New York: St. Martin's Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marsh. D. (1976). On joining interest groups: An empirical consideration of the work of Mancur Olson Jr. British Journal of Political Science 6: 257–271.

    Google Scholar 

  • McLean, I. (2000). The divided legacy of Mancur Olson.British Journal of Political Science 30: 651–668.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moe, T. (1980). The organization of interests. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mill, J.S. ([1848] 1965). Principles of political economy, seventh edition, Vol. 3, Bk. 5.Toronto: University of Toronto Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, A. (1981). Albert Einstein's special theory of relativity: emergence (1905) and early interpretation (1905–1911). Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.

  • Mueller, D. (1998). In memoriam, Mancur Olson, 1932–1998. Public Choice 97: 531–534.

    Google Scholar 

  • Musgrave, R. 1939. The voluntary exchange theory of public economy Quarterly Journal of Economics 53: 213–237.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditures. The Review of Economics and Statistics 36: 387–389.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. (1955). Diagramatic exposition of a theory of public expenditures. Review of Economics and Statistics 37: 350–356.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. (1958). Aspects of public expenditure theories, Review of Economics and Statistics 40: 332–338.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandler, T. (1992). Collective action: Theory and applications. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Syrett, H.C. and Cooke, J.E. (Eds.) (1962-). The papers of Alexander Hamilton. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tiebout, C.M. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy 64: 416–424.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Dougherty, K.L. Public Goods Theory from Eighteenth Century Political Philosophy to Twentieth Century Economics. Public Choice 117, 239–253 (2003). https://doi.org/10.1023/B:PUCH.0000003734.55916.8d

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1023/B:PUCH.0000003734.55916.8d

Keywords

Navigation