Skip to main content
Log in

Policy Reform and the Free-Rider Problem

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We investigate policy reform in a modelwith both lobbying, which involves afree-rider problem, and ordinary rentseeking, which does not. These activitiesinvolve similar skills, so a reform whichreduces rents shifts labor into lobbying.Also, because of the free-rider problem,the marginal return to the industry fromlobbying may greatly exceed an individualfirm's return to lobbying. Thus, the shiftinto lobbying caused by rent reduction maylead to large increases in transfers to thelobbying industry. Under somecircumstances, a reform which reducesavailable rents increases total rents plustransfers to the industry.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Alesina, A. and Drazen, A. (1991). Why are stabilizations delayed? American Economic Review 81: 1170–1188.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G.S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics 98: 371–400.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhagwati, J.N. (1978). Foreign trade regimes and economic development: Anatomy and consequences of exchange control regimes. New York: NBER.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhagwati, J.N. (1982). Directly-unproductive, profit-seeking (DUP) activities. Journal of Political Economy 90: 988–1002.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhagwati, J.N., Brecher, R.A. and Srinivasan, T.N. (1984). DUP activities and economic theory. European Economic Review 24: 291–307.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhagwati, J.N. and Srinivasan, T.N. (1980). Revenue seeking: A generalization of the theory of tariffs. Journal of Political Economy 88: 1069–1087.

    Google Scholar 

  • Conlon, J. and Pecorino, P. (1998). Primary and secondary reform. Economic Inquiry36: 590–602.

    Google Scholar 

  • Drazen, A. and Grilli, V. (1993). The benefits of crises for economic reforms. American Economic Review 83: 598–607.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez, R. and Rodrik, D. (1991). Resistance to reform: Status quo bias in the presence of individual-specific uncertainty. American Economic Review 81: 1146–1155.

    Google Scholar 

  • Findlay, R. and Wellisz, S. (1982). Endogenous tariffs, the political economy of trade restrictions, and welfare. In J.N. Bhagwati (Ed.), Import competition and response, 245–258. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. and Helpman, E. (1994). Protection for sale. American Economic Review 84: 833–850.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hillman, A.L. (1991). Protection, politics, and market structure. In E. Helpman and A. Razin (Eds.), International trade and trade policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz, E., Nitzan, S. and Rosenberg, J. (1990). Rent-seeking for pure public goods. Public Choice 65: 49–60.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, A.O. (1974). The political economy of the rent-seeking society. American Economic Review 64: 291–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, A.O. (1978). Foreign trade regimes and economic development: Liberalization attempts and consequences. New York: NBER.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, A.O. (1990). The political economy of controls: American sugar. In M. Scott and D. Lal (Eds.), Public policy and economic development, 170–216. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lohmann, S. (1994). Information aggregation through costly political action. American Economic Review 84: 518–530.

    Google Scholar 

  • Magee, S.P., Brock, W.A. and Young, L. (1989). Black hole tariffs and endogenous policy theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayer, W. (1984). Endogenous tariff formation. American Economic Review 74: 970–985.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nitzan, S. (1991a). Collective rent dissipation. Economic Journal 101: 1522–1534.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nitzan, S. (1991b). Rent seeking with non-identical sharing rules. Public Choice 71: 43–50.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nitzan, S. (1994). Modeling rent-seeking contests. European Journal of Political Economy 10: 41–60.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pecorino, P. (1998). Is there a free-rider problem in lobbying: Endogenous tariffs, trigger strategies, and the number of firms. American Economic Review 88: 652–660.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (1986). Tariffs, subsidies, and welfare with endogenous policy. Journal of International Economics 21: 285–299.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (1994). The rush to free trade in the developing world: Why so late? Why now? Will it last? In S. Haggard and S.B. Webb (Eds.), Voting for reform: Democracy, political liberalization, and economic adjustment. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenthal, A. (1993). The third house: Lobbyists and lobbying in the states.Washington, D.C.: Congressional Quarterly Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1980). Efficient rent seeking. In J.M. Buchanan, R.D. Tollison and G. Tullock (Eds.), Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society.College Station, Texas: Texas A & M University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wärneryd, K. (1998). Distributional conflict and jurisdictional organization. Journal of Public Economics 69: 435–450.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Conlon, J.R., Pecorino, P. Policy Reform and the Free-Rider Problem. Public Choice 120, 123–142 (2004). https://doi.org/10.1023/B:PUCH.0000035858.33925.99

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1023/B:PUCH.0000035858.33925.99

Keywords

Navigation