Skip to main content
Log in

Budgetary Policy With Unified and Decentralized Appropriations Authority

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The divestiture of the House Appropriations Committee in the1880's has received considerable attention of an empiricalnature. This paper presents a formal model of legislativedecisionmaking, using a common agency formulation to representinterest group lobbying of legislators. This framework is usedto analyze the effects of decentralizing appropriationsauthority. The conditions under which decentralization leadsto higher spending are characterized. It is argued that theconventional view that divestiture caused higher levels ofspending only holds if decentralization created barriers tolobbying and political bargaining across different committees.In addition, the role of specialized committee knowledge isexamined.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

We’re sorry, something doesn't seem to be working properly.

Please try refreshing the page. If that doesn't work, please contact support so we can address the problem.

References

  • Auerbach, A.J. (1985). The theory of excess burden and optimal taxation. In A.J. Auerbach and M. Feldstein (Eds.), Handbook of public economics, 1: 61-127. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G.S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics 98: 371-400.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brady, D. and Morgan, M. (1987). Reforming the structure of the house appropriations process: The effects of the 1885 and 1919-20 reforms on money decisions. In M.D. McCubbins and T. Sullivan (Eds.), Congress: Structure and policy, 207-234. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cogan, J.F. (1994). The dispersion of spending authority and federal budget deficits. In J.F. Cogan, T.J. Muris and A. Schick (Eds.), The budget puzzle: Understanding federal spending, 16-40. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohn, M. (1988) (Ed.). Congress A to Z, Washington, DC: Congressional Quarterly Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crain, W.M. (1999). Districts, diversity, and fiscal biases: Evidence from the American states. Journal of Law and Economics 42: 675-698.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crain, W.M. and Muris, T.J. (1995). Legislative organization of fiscal policy. Journal of Law and Economics 38: 311-333.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dharmapala, D. (1999). Comparing tax expenditures and direct subsidies: The role of legislative committee structure. Journal of Public Economics 72: 421-454.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A.K. (1996). The making of economic policy: A transaction cost politics perspective. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A.K., Grossman, G.M. and Helpman, E. (1997). Common agency and coordination: General theory and application to government policy making. Journal of Political Economy 105: 752-769.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferejohn, J. and Krehbiel, K. (1987). The budget process and the size of the budget. American Journal of Political Science 31: 296-320.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilligan, T.W. and Krehbiel, K. (1987). Collective decisionmaking and standing committees: An informational rationale for restrictive amendment procedures. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization 3: 287-335.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilligan, T.W. and Matsusaka, J.G. (1995). Deviations from constituent interests: The role of legislative structure and political parties in the states. Economic Inquiry 33: 383-401.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilligan, T.W. and Matsusaka, J.G. (2001). Fiscal policy, legislature size, and political parties: Evidence from state and local governments in the first half of the 20th century. National Tax Journal 54: 57-82.

    Google Scholar 

  • Groseclose, T. and Snyder, J.M. Jr. (1996). Buying supermajorities. American Political Science Review 90: 303-315.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G.M. and Helpman, E. (1994). Protection for sale. American Economic Review 84: 833-850.

    Google Scholar 

  • Inman, R.P. and Fitts, M.A. (1990). Political institutions and fiscal policy: Evidence from the U.S. historical record. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization 6: 79-132.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kiewiet, D.R. and McCubbins, M.D. (1991). The logic of delegation: Congressional parties and the appropriations process. Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krehbiel, K. (1998). Pivotal politics: A theory of US lawmaking. Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myerson, R.B. (1993). Incentives to cultivate favored minorities under alternative electoral systems. American Political Science Review 87: 856-869.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stewart, C.H., III (1989). Budget reform politics: The design of the appropriations process in the House of Representatives, 1865-1921. Cambridge, MA, New York, NY and Melbourne: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Dharmapala, D. Budgetary Policy With Unified and Decentralized Appropriations Authority. Public Choice 115, 347–367 (2003). https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1024205130807

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1024205130807

Keywords

Navigation