Skip to main content
Log in

Globalization and Risky Human-Capital Investment

  • Published:
International Tax and Public Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Globalization is supposed to increase the mobility of highly skilled labor and to reduce governments' scope for redistribution. We show that this increases the private incentives for education and may decrease, but may also increase, the government's incentives to provide education subsidies in a framework in which education investment is risky. Globalization shifts the cost of these subsidies to the less skilled. For the welfare implications of globalization the availability of private insurance is crucial. Welfare unambiguously increases if such markets work.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Arnott, R. J. and J. E. Stiglitz. (1986). “Moral Hazard and Optimal Commodity Taxation.” Journal of Public Economics 29(1), 1-24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T. (1995). “Non-Market Institutions for Credit and Risk Sharing in Low-Income Countries.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 9, 115-127.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boadway, R., N. Marceau and M. Marchand. (1996). “Investment in Education and the Time Inconsistency of Redistributive Tax Policy.” Economica 63, 171-189.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boadway, R. and M. Marchand. (1995). “The Use of Public Expenditures for Redistributive Purposes.” Oxford Economic Papers 47, 45-59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cullen, J. B. and J. Gruber. (2000). “Does Unemployment Insurance Crowd out Spousal Labor Supply?” Journal of Labor Economics 18, 546-572.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cutler, D. M. and J. Gruber. (1995). “Does Public Insurance Crowd out Private Insurance?” NBER Working Paper No. 5082.

  • Dewatripont, M. and G. Roland. (2000). “Soft Budget Constraints, Transition, and Financial Systems.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 156, 245-260.

    Google Scholar 

  • DiTella, R. and R. MacCulloch. (1997). “Does the Welfare State Destroy the Family?” Oxford Applied Economics Discussion Paper No. 195.

  • Eaton, J. and H. S. Rosen. (1980). “Taxation, Human Capital, and Uncertainty.” American Economic Review 70, 705-715.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gorsky, M. (1998). “The Growth and Distribution of English Friendly Societies in the 19th Century.” Economic History Review 51, 489-511.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hagen, K. P., P. Osmundsen and G. Schjelderup. (1995). “Personal Income Taxation and Welfare Appropriation in an Open Economy.” Paper presented at the Tutzing Conference on Competition or Harmonization.

  • Horrell, S. and D. Oxley. (2000). “Work and Prudence: Household Responses to Income Variation in Nineteenth-Century Britain.” European Review of Economic History 4, 27-57.

    Google Scholar 

  • Justman, M. and J.-F. Thisse. (1997). “Implications of the Mobility of Skilled Labor for Local Public Funding of Higher Education.” Economics Letters 55, 409-412.

    Google Scholar 

  • Justman, M. and J.-F. Thisse. (2000). “Local Public Funding of Higher Education when Skilled Labor is Imperfectly Mobile.” International Tax and Public Finance 7, 247-258.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kehoe, P. J. (1989). “Policy Cooperation among Benevolent Governments May Be Undesirable.” Review of Economic Studies 56, 289-296.

    Google Scholar 

  • Konrad, K. A. (2001). “Privacy and Time Consistent Optimal Labor Income Taxation.” Journal of Public Economics 79, 503-519.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2001a). Education at a Glance: OECD Indicators. Paris.

  • OECD. (2001b). OECD in Figures, Statistics on the Member Countries. Paris.

  • Poutvaara, P. (1999). “Investment in Education and Redistributive Taxation without Precommitment.” Mimeo.

  • Poutvaara, P. (2000). “Education, Mobility of Labor and Tax Competition.” International Tax and Public Finance 7, 699-719.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poutvaara, P. and V. Kanniainen. (2000). “Why Invest in Your Neighbor? Social Contract on Education Investment.” International Tax and Public Finance 7, 547-563.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenzweig, M. R. (1988). “Risk, Implicit Contracts and the Family in Rural Areas of Low-Income Countries.” Economic Journal 98, 1148-1170.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shavell, S. (1979). “On Moral Hazard and Insurance.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 93, 541-562.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sinn, H.-W. (1996). “Social Insurance, Incentives and Risk Taking.” International Tax and Public Finance 3, 259-280.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stern, N. H. (1982). “Optimum Income Taxation with Errors in Administration.” Journal of Public Economics 17, 181-211.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. E. (1982). “Self-Selection and Pareto Efficient Taxation.” Journal of Public Economics 17, 213-240.

    Google Scholar 

  • Varian, H. R. (1980). “Redistributive Taxation as Social Insurance.” Journal of Public Economics 14, 49-68.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wildasin, D. (2000a). “Labor Market Integration, Investment in Risky Human Capital, and Fiscal Competition.” American Economic Review 90, 73-95.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wildasin, D. (2000b). “Factor Mobility and Fiscal Policy in the EU: Policy Issues and Analytical Approaches.” Economic Policy 31, 337-378.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, J. D. and D.Wildasin. (1996). “Imperfect Mobility and Local Government Behaviour in an Overlapping-Generations Model.” Journal of Public Economics 60, 177-198.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Andersson, F., Konrad, K.A. Globalization and Risky Human-Capital Investment. International Tax and Public Finance 10, 211–228 (2003). https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1023862229689

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1023862229689

Navigation