Skip to main content
Log in

Political Coase Theorem

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This article considers theapplicability of the Coase theorem (in bothits positive and normative formulations) tothe political market. The articleanalogizes the choice of decision rules inthe political market to the choice of legalrules in the traditional Coase theorem andfurther analogizes alternative initialcoalitions to the different initialallocations of entitlements considered byCoase (1960). On the basis of theseanalogies, the paper examines the relevance(or lack thereof) of alternative votingrules and initial coalitions on the finalpolitical outcome. The article furthershows that, if all voters are allowed toenter into Coasian bargaining over thepolicy outcome to be adopted by themajority coalition (i.e., if politicalbargains are possible and are enforceable),uniqueness and stability are obtained. Theanalysis of the axiomatic Nash bargainingequilibrium yields an interesting geometricintuition. If voters have similar utilityfunctions centered around different idealpolicy points, the Coasian bargaining willbe conducive to the ``center of mass'' of thepolicy space, which weighs the agents'preferences as revealed in the bargainingprocess. Such ideal equilibrium satisfiesmost criteria of social welfare. Thearticle concludes considering the variouspractical limits of this ideal politicalmarket, whenever collective action andagency problems affect the politicalbargaining in a representative or directdemocracy.

With all side payments prohibited,there is no assurance that collectiveaction will be taken in the most productiveway. (James M. Buchanan and Gordon Tullock, 1962)

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

Cases and Statutes

  • Davisv. Bandemer, 478 U.S. 109, 124 (1986).

    Google Scholar 

  • Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2, 9 (1984).

    Google Scholar 

  • {tiLine Item Veto Act. } Pub. L. No. 104-130, 110 Stat. 1200 (1996) (codified at 2 U.S.C.A. § 691 (West 1997)).

  • New York v. Clinton, 985 F. Supp. 168 (D.D.C. 1998).

Books and Journal Articles

  • Arrow, K. (1963).Social choice and individual values. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G.S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence.Quarterly Journal of Economics 98: 371-400.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G.S. (1985). Public policies, groups, and dead weight costs. Journal of Public Economics 28: 329.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernholz, P. (1973). Logrolling, arrow paradox and cyclical majorities. Public Choice 15: 87.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernholz, P. (1980). A general social dilemma: Profitable exchange and intransitive group preferences. Zeitschrift für National Ökonomie 40: 1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernholz, P. (1982). Externalities as a necessary condition for cyclical social preferences.Quarterly Journal of Economics 97: 699.

    Google Scholar 

  • Broder, D. (1997). Catatonic politics. Washington Post (Nov. 11).

  • Buchanan, J. and Tullock G. (1962). The calculus of consent: Logical foundations of constitutional democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calabresi, G. (1968). Transaction costs, resource allocation and liability rules. A comment.Journal of Law and Economics 11: 67.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calabresi, G. and Douglas, M.A. (1972). Property rules, liability rules and inalienabilty: One view of the cathedral. Harvard Law Review 85: 1089-1128.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiang, A. (1984). Fundamental methods of mathematical economics. New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law & Economics 3: 2.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1974). The lighthouse in economics. Journal of Law and Economics 17: 357-376.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1988). Notes on the problem of social cost. In: Coase, R. (Ed.), The firm, the market, and the law. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J. (1966). The possibility of a social welfare function. The American Economics Review 56: 1105.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J. (1967). The possibility of a social welfare function: Reply. The American Economics Review 57: 1311.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooter, R. (1987). Coase theorem. In: J. Eatwell, M. Milgate and P. Newman (Eds.), The new Palgrave. A dictionary of economics 1: 457.

  • Cooter, R.D. (2000). The strategic constitution. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooter, R. and Ulen, T. (1997). Law and economics. Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crain W.M., Leavens, D.R. and Tollison, R.D. (1986). Final voting in legislatures. American Economic Review 76: 833-841.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (1964). The exchange and enforcement of property rights. Journal of Law and Economics 7: 11.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (1967). Toward a theory of property rights. American Economics Review 57: 347.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dewar, H. (1997). Sen. Helms' Gavel leaves Weld nomination in Limbo. Washington Post (Sept. 13).

  • Dixit, A. and Olson, M., Jr. (1997). Does voluntary participation undermine the Coase theorem? Unpublished manuscript.

  • Dixon, A. (1985). Line-item veto controversy. Congressional Digest 64: 282.

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterbrook, F. (1983). Statutes' domains. University of Chicago Law Review 50: 547.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edgeworth, F.Y. (1881). Mathematical psychics.

  • Elhauge, E. (1991). Does interest group theory justify more intrusive judicial review? Yale Law Journal 101: 41.

    Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, R. (1984). Toward a revitalization of the contract clause. University of Chicago Law Review 51: 703.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eskridge, W., Jr. (1988). Politics without romance: Implications of public choice theory for statutory interpretation. Virginia Law Review 74: 275.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gughotta, G. (1997). Wheeling and dealing and keeping score on the ‘fast track’. Washington Post (Nov. 26).

  • Heidorn, R., Jr. (1994). Fateful vote stays at center stage. Philadelphia Inquirer (Nov. 2).

  • Heidorn, R., Jr. (1994). Margolies-Mezvinsky: Voted out of office but hardly defeated.Philadelphia Inquirer (Dec. 24).

  • Kahn, P. (1990). The politics of unregulation: Public choice and limits on government. Cornell Law Review 75: 306 n. 101.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karlan, P. (1999). Symposium commentary: Politics by other means. Virginia Law Review 85: 1697.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koford, K. (1982). Why so much stability? Centralized vote trading. Public Choice 39: 245.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kronman, A. (1985). Contracts and the state of nature. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 1: 3.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levine, M. and Plott, C. (1977). Agenda influence and its implications. Virginia Law Review 63: 561.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levinson, D. (1999). Symposium commentary: Market failures and failures of markets.Virginia Law Review 85: 1745.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levmore, S. (1989). Parliamentary law, majority decisionmaking, and the voting paradox.Virginia Law Review 75: 971.

    Google Scholar 

  • Macey, J. (1986). Promoting public-regarding legislation through statutory interpretation: An interest group model. Columbia Law Review 86: 223.

    Google Scholar 

  • Macey, J. (1997). Public and private ordering and the production of legitimate and illegitimate legal rules. Cornell Law Review 82: 1137-1139.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, N. (1977). Logrolling, vote trading, and the paradox of voting: A game of theoretical overview. Public Choice 30: 51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. (1967). The possibility of a social welfare function: Comment. American Economics Review 57: 1304.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. (1989). Public choice II. Cambridge, UK; New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D., Philpotts, G. and Vanek, J. (1972). The social gains from exchanging votes: A simulation. Public Choice 13: 55.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nash, J. (1950). The bargaining problem. Econometrica 18: 155.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ordeshook, P. (1997). The spatial analysis of elections and committees: Four decades of research. In: D. Mueller (Ed.), Perspectives on public choice: A handbook. Cambridge, U.K.; New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parisi, F. (1995). Private property and social costs. European Journal of Law and Economics 2: 149.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parisi, F. (1998). The market for votes: Coasian bargaining in an Arrovian setting. George Mason Law Review 6: 745.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parisi, F. (2001). The asymmetric Coase theorem: Dual remedies for a unified property. George Mason University Law and Economics Working Papers # 01.

  • Park, R. (1967). The possibility of a social welfare function: Comment. American Economics Review 57: 1300.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (1990). How efficient is the voting market? Journal of Law and Economics 33: 27-63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Penny, T. (1997). Pork is safe from this president's line-item vetoes. Wall Street Journal (Nov. 13).

  • Riggs, R. (1973). Separation of powers: Congressional riders and the veto power. University of Michigan Journal of Law Reform 6: 743.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, G. (1988). Public choice speculations on the item veto. Virginia Law Review 74: 407.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roemer, J. (1996). Theories of distributive justice. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogers, D. (1997). Clinton warns he's prepared to veto spending bills if changes aren't made.Wall Street Journal (Oct. 2).

  • Rowley, C.K. (1993). Public choice (3 Vols.). Edward Elgar Publishing.

  • Schwartz, T. (1977). Collective choice, separation of issues and vote trading. American Political Science Review 71: 999.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K. and Weingast, B. (1984). Uncovered sets and sophisticated voting outcomes with implications for agenda control. American Journal of Political Science 28: 49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shubik, M. (1982). Game theory in the social sciences: Concepts and solutions. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sidak, J. and Smith, T. (1990). Four faces of the item veto: A reply to Tribe and Kurland.Northwestern University Law Review 84: 437.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stearns, M. (1992). The public choice case against the item veto. Washington & Lee Law Review 49: 399.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stearns, M. (1994). The misguided renaissance of social choice. Yale Law Journal 103: 1219.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stearns, M. (1995). Standing back from the forest: Justiciability and social choice. California Law Review 83: 1384.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G.J. (1966). The theory of price 113 (3d ed.).

  • Stigler, G.J. (1971). Economic competition and political competition. Public Choice 13: 91-106.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G.J. (1972). The law and economics of public policy: A plea to the scholars. Journal of Legal Studies 1: 1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stout, L. (1992). Strict scrutiny and social choice: An economic inquiry into fundamental rights and suspect classifications. Georgetown Law Journal 80: 1787.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1981). Why so much stability? Public Choice 37: 189.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1998). On voting: A public choice approach. Cheltenham, U.K.: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vikrey, W. (1960). Utility, strategy, and social decision rules. Quarterly Journal of Economics 74: 507.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yang, J. and Pianin, E. (1997). Final push for fast trade. Washington Post (Nov. 8).

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Parisi, F. Political Coase Theorem. Public Choice 115, 1–36 (2003). https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1022877303100

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1022877303100

Keywords

Navigation