Skip to main content
Log in

Renegotiation and Relative Performance Evaluation: Why an Informative Signal May Be Useless

  • Published:
Review of Accounting Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Although Holmström's informativeness criterionprovides a theoretical foundation for the controllability principleand interfirm relative performance evaluation, empirical and fieldstudies provide only weak evidence on such practices. This paperrefines the traditional informativeness criterion by abandoning theconventional full-commitment assumption. With the possibility ofrenegotiation, a signal's usefulness in incentive contractingdepends on its information quality, not simply on whether the signalis informative. This paper derives conditions for determining when asignal is useless and when it is useful. In particular, theseconditions will be met when the signal's information quality iseither sufficiently poor or sufficiently rich. (JEL C72,D82).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Amershi, A., R. Banker, and S. Datar. (1990). Economic Sufficiency and Statistical Sufficiency in the Aggregation of Accounting Signals. Accounting Review 65, 113-130.

    Google Scholar 

  • Antle, R., and J. Demski. (1988). “The Controllability Principle in Responsibility Accounting.” Accounting Review LXIII, 700-718.

    Google Scholar 

  • Antle, R., and A. Smith. (1986). “An Empirical Investigation of Relative Performance Evaluation of Corporate Executives.” Journal of Accounting Research 24, 1-39.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arya, A., J. Glover, and K. Sivaramakrishnan. (1997). “Commitment Issues in Budgeting.” Journal of Accounting Research 35, 273-278.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baiman, S., and J. S. Demski. (1980). “Economically Optimal Performance Evaluation and Control Systems.” Journal of Accounting Research 18, 184-220.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berge, C. (1963). Topological Spaces, translated by Patterson from French original, 1959. New York: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bushman, R. M., R. J. Indjejikian, and A. Smith. (1996). “CEOCompensation: The Role of Individual Performance Evaluation.” Journal of Accounting and Economics 21, 161-193.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coughlin, A., and R. Schmidt. (1985). “Executive Compensation, Management Turnover, and Firm Performance: An Empirical Investigation.” Journal of Accounting and Economics 7, 43-66.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crawford, V. P. (1990). “Equilibrium without Independence.” Journal of Economic Theory 50, 127-154.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demski, J. S., and H. Frimor. (1999). “Performance Measure Garbling Under Renegotiation in Multi-period Agencies.” Journal of Accounting Research 37, 187-214.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dewatripont, M. (1989). “Renegotiation and Information Revelation over Time: The Case of Optimal Labor Contracts.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 104, 589-620.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frederickson, J. R. (1990). “Relative Performance Information: The Effects of Common Uncertainty and Contract Type on Agent Effort.” Accounting Review 67, 647-669.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg, D., and J. Tirole. (1990). “Moral Hazard and Renegotiation in Agency Contracts.” Econometrica 58, 1279-1319.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibbons, R., and K. Murphy. (1990). “Relative Performance Evaluation for Chief Executive Officers.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 43, 30s-51s.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harris, M., and R. M. Townsend. (1981). “Resource Allocation under Asymmetric Information.” Econometrica 49, 33-64.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harsanyi, J. C. (1973). “Games with Randomly Disturbed Payoffs: A New Rationale for Mixed Strategy Equilibrium Points.” International Journal of Game Theory 2, 1-23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hart, O., and J. Tirole. (1988). “Contract Renegotiation and Coasian Dynamics.” Review of Economic Studies 55, 509-540.

    Google Scholar 

  • HolmstrÖm, B. (1979). “Moral Hazard and Observability.” Bell Journal of Economics 10, 74-91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Indjejikian, R. J., and D. Nanda. (1999). “Dynamic Incentives and Responsibility Accounting.” Journal of Accounting and Economics 27, 177-201.

    Google Scholar 

  • Janakiraman, S. N., R. A. Lambert, and D. F. Larcker. (1992). “An Empirical Investigation of the Relative Performance Evaluation Hypothesis.” Journal of Accounting Research 30, 53-69.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jewitt, I. (1988). “Justifying the First-Order Approach to Principal-Agent Problems.” Econometrica 56, 1177-1190.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laffont, J. J., and J. Tirole. (1990). “Adverse Selection and Renegotiation in Procurement.” Review of Economic Studies 57, 597-625.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ma, C.-T. A. (1991). “Adverse Selection in Dynamic Moral Hazard.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 106, 255-275.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ma, C.-T. A. (1994). “Renegotiation and Optimality in Agency Contracts.” Review of Economic Studies 61, 109-129.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maher, M. W. (1987). “The Use of Relative Performance Evaluation in Organizations.” In William J. Bruns, Jr. and Robert S. Kaplan (eds.) Accounting & Management: Field Study Perspectives, Boston, Mass.: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marschak, J. (1972). “Optimal Systems for Information and Decision.” In Economic Information, Decision, and Prediction-Selected Essays: Volume II. Dordrecht, Holland: D. Reidel Publishing Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Merchant, K. A. (1987). “How and Why Firms Disregard the Controllability Principle.” In William J. Bruns, Jr. and Robert S. Kaplan (eds.), Accounting & Management: Field Study Perspectives. Boston, Mass.: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, K. (1985). “Corporate Performance and Managerial Remuneration.” Journal of Accounting and Economics 7, 11-42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myerson, R. B. (1979). “Incentive Compatibility and the Bargaining Problem.” Econometrica 47, 61-73.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosen, S. (1992). “Contracts and the Market for Executives.” In Lars Werin and Hans Wijkander (eds.), Contract Economics, Cambridge, Mass. and Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. E. (1977). “Monopoly, Non-linear Pricing and Imperfect Information: The Insurance Market.” Review of Economic Studies 44, 407-430.

    Google Scholar 

  • Takayama, A. (1985). Mathematical Economics, 2nd ed. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wolfson, M. A. (1985). “Tax, Incentive, and Risk-sharing Issues in the Allocation of Property Rights: The Generalized Lease-or-Buy Problem.” Journal of Business 58, 159-171.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yim, A. T. (1995). “Renegotiable Contracts and Monitoring Information.” Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Yale University.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Andrew Tzelung Yim.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Yim, A.T. Renegotiation and Relative Performance Evaluation: Why an Informative Signal May Be Useless. Review of Accounting Studies 6, 77–108 (2001). https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1011386104784

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1011386104784

Navigation