Advertisement

Journal of Risk and Uncertainty

, Volume 22, Issue 1, pp 79–93 | Cite as

Are Event-Splitting Effects Actually Boundary Effects?

  • Steven J. Humphrey
Article

Abstract

An event-splitting effect (ESE) occurs when an event, which yields a positive outcome in one lottery but zero under another, is separated into two sub-events and this increases the relative attractiveness of the former lottery. ESEs are attributed to either (1) a preference for more positive outcomes in lotteries, or (2) an aversion to more zero outcomes. An experiment is reported which replicates ESEs whilst controlling for explanation (2). This favours explanation (1), but a lack of generality in replication suggests previous ESEs to be partially due to (2). Implications are discussed for a related choice phenomena, decision theory, and real-world decision-making.

event-splitting effects boundary effects experimental economics 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Conlisk, J. (1989). “Three Variants on the Allais Example,” American Economic Review 79, 392–407.Google Scholar
  2. Harless, D. W. and C. Camerer. (1994). “The Predictive Utility of Generalized Expected Utility Theories,” Econometrica 62, 1251–1291.Google Scholar
  3. Humphrey, S. J. (1995). “Regret-Aversion or Event-Splitting Effects? More Evidence Under Risk and Uncertainty,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 11, 263–274.Google Scholar
  4. Humphrey, S. J. (1996). “Do Anchoring Effects Underline Event-Splitting Effects? An Experimental Test,” Economics Letters 51, 303–308.Google Scholar
  5. Humphrey, S. J. (1998). “More Mixed Results on Boundary Effects,” Economics Letters 61, 79–84.Google Scholar
  6. Humphrey, S. J. (1999). “Probability Learning, Event-Splitting Effects and the Economic Theory of Choice,” Theory and Decision 46, 51–78.Google Scholar
  7. Humphrey, S. J. (2000). “The Common Consequence Effect: Testing a Unified Explanation of Recent Mixed Evidence,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 41, 239–262.Google Scholar
  8. Johnson, E. J., J. Hershey, J. Meszaros, and H. Kunreuther. (1993). “Framing, Probability Distortions, and Insurance Decisions,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 7, 35–51.Google Scholar
  9. Kahneman, D. and A. Tversky. (1979). “Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision Under Risk,” Econometrica 47, 263–291.Google Scholar
  10. Loomes, G. and R. Sugden. (1987). “Some Implications of a More General Form of Regret Theory,” Journal of Economic Theory 41, 270–287.Google Scholar
  11. Neilson, W. S. (1992). “Some Mixed Results on Boundary Effects,” Economics Letters 39, 275–278.Google Scholar
  12. Sopher, B. and G. Gigliotti. (1990). “A Test of Generalized Expected Utility Theory,” mimeo. Department of Economics, Rutgers University.Google Scholar
  13. Starmer, C. (1999). “Cycling with Rules of Thumb: A Test of a New Form of Non-Transitive Choice,” Theory and Decision 46, 139–157.Google Scholar
  14. Starmer, C. and R. Sugden. (1993). “Testing for Juxtaposition and Event-Splitting Effects,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 6, 235–254.Google Scholar
  15. Tversky, A. and D. Kahneman. (1986). “The Framing of Decisions and the Psychology of Choice,” Science 211, 453–458.Google Scholar
  16. Tversky, A. and D. J. Koehler. (1994). “Support Theory: A Nonextensional Representation of Subjective Probability,” Psychological Review 101, 547–567.Google Scholar
  17. Viscusi, W. K. (1989). “Prospective Reference Theory: Toward an Explanation of the Paradoxes,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 2, 235–264.Google Scholar
  18. Weber, M., F. Eisenfuhr, and D. von Winterfeldt. (1988). “The Effects of Splitting Attributes on Weights in Multiattribute Utility Measurement,” Management Science 34, 431–445.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Kluwer Academic Publishers 2001

Authors and Affiliations

  • Steven J. Humphrey
    • 1
  1. 1.School of EconomicsUniversity of NottinghamNottinghamUK

Personalised recommendations