Abstract
The "Moralist" camp takes environmental morale to be essential in order to save nature. The "Rationalist" camp, mainly represented by economists, takes market-based instruments solely relying on extrinsic motivation to be both necessary and sufficient for a successful environmental policy. Recently, the moralists have learned to appreciate economists' incentive instruments, and rationalists have learned that environmental morale is required to find political support for the introduction of their preferred instruments.
Intrinsic motivation in the form of environmental morale is moreover closely connected to the extrinsic motivation via crowding effects. Economic incentives – in particular tradeable emission rights and emission taxes – tend to undermine environmental morale while policy instruments tend to raise it.
An environmental policy based on complementarity is able to exploit the advantages, and to weaken the disadvantages, of the policies proposed by the two camps. Market-based instruments should be accompanied by policies informing and inviting the consumers to engage. In addition, possibilities to participate in the decision-making about environmental policy should be offered (preferably via direct democracy), and the policy should be decided and undertaken at the lowest possible level, normally the local community level.
This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.
REFERENCES
Akerlof, G. A. (1989). The economics of illusion. Economics and Politics, 1, 1-15.
Alchian, A. A., & Demsetz, H. (1972). Production, information costs and economic organization. American Economic Review, 62, 777-795.
Barkema, H. G. (1995). Do job executives work harder when they are monitored? Kyklos, 48, 19-42.
Baumol, W. J., & Oates, W. E. (1979). Economics, environmental policy, and the quality of life. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
Becker, G. S. (1976). The economic approach to human behavior. Chicago: Chicago University Press.
Blinder, A. S. (1987). Hard heads, soft hearts. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.
Bohnet, I., & Frey, B. S. (1999). The sound of silence in prisoner's dilemma and dictator games. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 38, 43-57.
Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1975). Pollutors' profits and political response: Direct controls versus taxes. American Economic Review, 65, 139-147.
Budge, I. (1996). The new challenge of direct democracy. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Butler, D., & Ranney, A. (Eds.) (1994). Referendums around the world. The growing use of direct democracy. Washington, DC: AEI Press.
Cameron, J., & Pierce, W. D. (1994). Reinforcement, reward, and intrinsic motivation: A meta-analysis. Review of Educational Research, 64, 363-423.
Cooter, R. D. (1984). Prices and sanctions. Columbia Law Review, 84, 1523-1560.
Cooter, R. D. (1994). Laws and prices: How economics contributed to law by misunderstanding morality. Berkeley, CA: University of California at Berkeley. Working Paper No. 94-2, Program in Law and Economics.
Cronin, T. E. (1989). Direct democracy. The politics of initiative, referendum and recall. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Cropper, M. L., & Oates, W. E. (1992). Environmental economics: A survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 30, 675-740.
Dawes, R. M., McTavish, J., & Shaklee, H. (1977). Behavior, communication, and assumptions about other people's behavior in a commons dilemma situation. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 35, 1-11.
Dawes, R. M. (1988). Rational choice in an uncertain world. San Diego, CA: Harcourt, Brace, Jovanovich.
Dawes, R. M., van de Kragt, A. J. C., & Orbell, J. M. (1988). Not me or thee but We: The importance of group identity in eliciting cooperation in dilemma situations — Experimental manipulations. Acta Psychologica, 68, 83-97.
Deci, E. L. (1971). Effects of externally mediated rewards on intrinsic motivation. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 18, 105-115.
Deci, E. L., & Ryan, R. M. (1985). Intrinsic motivation and self-determination in human behavior. New York: Plenum Press.
Deci, E. L., Koestner, R., & Ryan, R. M. (forthcoming). Extrinsic rewards and intrinsic motivation: A clear and consistent picture after all. Psychological Bulletin.
De Young, R. (1985–1986). Encouraging environmentally appropriate behavior: The role of intrinsic motivation. Journal of Environmental Systems, 15, 281-292.
Diekmann, A. (1995). Umweltbewusstsein oder Anreizstrukturen? Empirische Befunde zum Energiesparen, der Verkehrsmittelwahl und zum Konsumverhalten. In: A. Diekmann & A. Franzen (Eds.), Kooperatives Umwelthandeln. Modelle, Erfahrungen, Massnahmen, pp. 39-68. Chur: Rüegger.
Diekmann, A., & Preisendörfer, P. (1993). Persönliches Umweltverhalten. Diskrepanzen zwischen Anspruch und Wirklichkeit. Kölner Zeitschrift für Soziologie und Sozialpsychologie, 44, 226-251.
Diekmann, A., & Preisendörfer, P. (1998). Umweltbewusstsein und Umweltverhalten in Low-und High-Cost-Situationen. Eine empirische Untersuchung der Low-Cost-Hypothese. Bern: University of Bern, Institute of Sociology. Mimeo.
Eisenberger, R., & Cameron, J. (1996). Detrimental effects of reward. Reality or myth? American Psychologist, 51, 1153-1166.
Fama, E. F., & Jensen, M. C. (1983). Separation of ownership and control. Journal of Law and Economics, 26, 301-351.
Faulhaber, G. R., & Baumol, W. J. (1988). Economists as innovators. Journal of Economic Literature, 26, 577-600.
Frey, B. S. (1997a). Not just for the money. An economic theory of personal motivation. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
Frey, B. S. (1997b). A constitution for knaves crowds out civic virtues. Economic Journal, 107, 1043-1053.
Frey, B. S. (1999). Economics as a science of human behaviour. Boston: Kluwer.
Frey, B. S., & Bohnet, I. (1995). Institutions affect fairness: Experimental investigations. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 151, 286-303.
Frey, B. S., & Oberholzer-Gee, F. (1997). The cost of price incentives: An empirical analysis of motivation crowding-out. American Economic Review, 87, 746-755.
Frey, B. S., & Schneider, F. (1997). Warum wird die Umweltökonomie kaum angewendet? Journal of Environmental Law and Policy/Zeitschrift für Umweltpolitik & Umweltrecht, 2, 153-170.
Goodin, R. E. (1994). Selling environmental indulgences. Kyklos, 47, 573-596.
Gouldner, A. W. (1960). The norm of reciprocity: A preliminary statement. American Sociological Review, 25, 161-178.
Grant, R. M. (1996). Toward a knowledge-based theory of the firm. Strategic Management Journal, 17 (Winter Special Issue), 109-122.
Hahn, R. W. (1989). The political economy of environment regulation: Towards a unifying framework. Public Choice, 65, 21-47.
Hopper, J. R., & Nielsen, J. M. (1991). Recycling as altruistic behavior. Normative and behavioral strategies to expand participation in a community recycling program. Environment and Behavior, 23, 195-220.
Ichniowski, C., Shaw, K., & Prennushi, G. (1997). The effects of human resource management practices on productivity: A study of steel finishing lines. American Economic Review, 87, 291-313.
Jensen, M. C. (1992). Reputational spillovers, innovation, licensing and entry. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 10, 193-212.
Kahneman, D., Slovic, P., & Tversky, A. (Eds.) (1982). Judgement under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Kazdin, A. E. (1982). The token economy: A decade later. Journal of Applied Behavioral Analysis, 15, 431-445.
Kelman, S. (1981). What price incentives? Economists and the environment. Boston: Auburn.
Kirchgässner, G. (1992). Towards a theory of low-cost decisions. European Journal of Political Economy, 8, 305-320.
Kliemt, H. (1986). The veil of insignificance. European Journal of Political Economy, 2, 333-344.
Ledyard, J. O. (1995). Public goods: A survey of experimental research. In: J. Kagel & A. E. Roth (Eds.), Handbook of experimental economics, pp. 111-194. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Lepper, M. R., & Greene, D. (Eds.) (1978). The hidden costs of reward: New perspectives on the psychology of human motivation. Hillsdale, NY: Erlbaum.
Mueller, D. C. (1989). Public choice II (2nd ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Mueller, D. C. (Ed.) (1997). Perspectives on public choice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
OECD (1994). Integrating environment and economics: The role of economic instruments. Paris: Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development.
Ölander, F., & Thøgersen, J. (1995). Understanding of consumer behaviour as a prerequisite for environmental protection. Journal of Consumer Policy, 18, 345-385.
Pittman, T. S., & Heller, J. F. (1987). Social motivation. Annual Review of Psychology, 38, 461-489.
Renn, O., Webler, T., & Wiedemann, P. (1995). Competence and fairness in citizen participation. Evaluating models for environmental discourse. Dordrecht: Kluwer.
Rousseau, D. M. (1995). Psychological contracts in organizations. Understanding written and unwritten agreements. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
Rotter, J. B. (1966). Generalized expectancies for internal versus external control of reinforcement. Psychological Monographs, 80 (1, Whole No. 609).
Rummel, A., & Feinberg, R. (1988). Cognitive evaluation theory: A meta-analytic review of the literature. Social Behavior and Personality, 16, 147-164.
Schoemaker, P. J. (1982). The expected utility model: Its variants, purposes, evidence and limitations. Journal of Economic Literature, 20, 529-563.
Stajkovic, A.D., & Luthans, F. (1997). A meta-analysis of the effects of organizational behavior modification on task performance, 1975–1995. Academy of Management Journal, 40, 1122-1149.
Stavins, R. N. (1998). Economic incentives for environmental regulation. In: P. Newman (Ed.), The new Palgrave dictionary of economics and the law, Vol. 2, pp. 6-13. London: Macmillan.
Stuart, C. E. (1984). Welfare costs per dollar of additional tax revenue in the United States. American Economic Review, 74, 352-362.
Sugden, R. (1989). Spontaneous order. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3(4), 85-98.
Sunstein, C. R. (1997). Free markets and social justice. New York: Oxford University Press.
Tang, S.-H., & Hall, C. V. (1995). The overjustification effect: A meta-analysis. Applied Cognitive Psychology, 9, 365-404.
Thaler, R. H. (1992). The winner's curse. Paradoxes and anomalies of economic life. New York: Free Press.
Thøgersen, J. (1994). Monetary incentives and environmental concern. Effects of a differentiated garbage fee. Journal of Consumer Policy, 17, 407-442.
Thorndike, E. L. (1933). An experimental study of rewards. Teachers College Contributions to Education, No. 580.
Tietenberg, T. (1985). Emissions trading: An exercise in reforming pollution policy. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.
Weck-Hannemann, H., & Frey, B. S. (1995). Are incentive instruments as good as economists believe? Some new considerations. In: L. Bovenberg & S. Cnossen (Eds.), Public economics and the environment in an imperfect world, pp. 173-186. Dordrecht: Kluwer.
Wiersma, U. J. (1992). The effects of extrinsic rewards on intrinsic motivation: A metaanalysis. Journal of Occupational and Organizational Psychology, 65, 101-114.
Williamson, O. E. (1975). Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications. New York: Free Press.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Frey, B.S. Morality and Rationality in Environmental Policy. Journal of Consumer Policy 22, 395–417 (1999). https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1006256117094
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1006256117094
Keywords
- Local Community
- Economic Policy
- Environmental Policy
- Community Level
- Intrinsic Motivation