Public Choice

, Volume 97, Issue 3, pp 257–293 | Cite as

Multiparty electoral competition in the Netherlands and Germany: A model based on multinomial probit

  • Normal Schofield
  • Andrew D. Martin
  • Kevin M. Quinn
  • Andrew B. Whitford

Abstract

A typical assumption of electoral models of party competition is that parties adopt policy positions so as to maximize expected vote share. Here we use Euro-barometer survey data and European elite-study data from 1979 for the Netherlands and Germany to construct a stochastic model of voter response, based on multinomial probit estimation. For each of these countries, we estimate a pure spatial electoral voting model and a joint spatial model. The latter model also includes individual voter and demographic characteristics. The pure spatial models for the two countries quite accurately described the electoral response as a stochastic function of party positions. We use these models to perform a thought experiment so as to estimate the expected vote maximizing party positions. We go on to propose a model of internal party decision-making based both on pre-election electoral estimation and post-election coalition bargaining. This model suggests why the various parties in the period in question did not adopt vote maximizing positions. We argue that maximizing expected vote will not, in general, be a rational party strategy in multiparty political systems which are based on proportional representation.

References

  1. Albert, J.H. and Chib, S. (1993). Bayesian analysis of binary and polychotomous response data. Journal of the American Statistical Association88: 669-679.Google Scholar
  2. Alvarez, R.M. and Nagler, J. (1996). Correlated disturbances in discrete choice models: A comparison of multinomial probit models and logit models. Typescript. Pasadena: California Institute of Technology.Google Scholar
  3. Aranson, P., Hinich, M. and Ordeshook, P. (1974). Election goals and strategies: Equivalent and non-equivalent candidate objectives. American Political Science Review68: 135-152.Google Scholar
  4. Axelrod, R. (1970). Conflict of interest. Chicago: Markham.Google Scholar
  5. Budge, I., Robertson, D. and Hearl, D. (Eds.). (1987). Ideology, strategy and party change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  6. Chib, S. and Greenberg, E. (1996). Multinomial probit by Markov Chain Monte Carlo. Typescript. Washington University in St. Louis.Google Scholar
  7. Coughlin, P. (1992). Probabilistic voting theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  8. Cox, G.W. (1984). An expected utility model of electoral competition. Quality and Quantity18: 337-349.Google Scholar
  9. Cox, G.W. (1987). The uncovered set and the core. American Journal of Political Science408-422.Google Scholar
  10. de Swaan, A. (1973). Coalition theories and cabinet formations. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
  11. Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
  12. Duverger, J. (1954). Political parties: Their organization and activity in the modern state. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
  13. Duverger, J. (1984). Which is the best electoral system? In A. Lijphart and B. Grofman (Eds.), Choosing an electoral system. New York: Praeger.Google Scholar
  14. Enelow, J.M. and Hinich, J.J. (1984). The spatial theory of voting: An introduction. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  15. Feddersen, T.J. (1992). A voting model implying Duverger's law and positive turnout. American Journal of Political Science34: 1005-1016.Google Scholar
  16. Herman, V. and Pope, J. (1973). Minority governments in western democracies. British Journal of Political Science3: 191-212.Google Scholar
  17. Hinich, M.J. (1977). Equilibrium in spatial voting: The median voter result is an artifact. Journal of Economic Theory16: 208-219.Google Scholar
  18. Hotelling, H. (1929). Stability in competition. Economic Journal39: 41-57.Google Scholar
  19. ISEIUM. (1983). European elections study: European political parties' middle-level elites. Europa-Institut, Universitat Mannheim.Google Scholar
  20. Kass, R.E. and Raftery, A.E. (1995). Bayes factors. Journal of the American Statistical Association90: 773-795.Google Scholar
  21. Keesing's Contemporary Archives. Harlow: Longman.Google Scholar
  22. Kramer, G.H. (1978). Existence of electoral equilibrium. In P. Ordeshook (Ed.), Game theory and political science. New York: New York University Press.Google Scholar
  23. Laver, M. and Schofield, N. (1990). Multiparty governments. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  24. Lin, T., Enelow, J. and Dorussen, H. (1996). Equilibrium in multicandidate probabilistic spatial voting. Typescript. University of Texas, Austin.Google Scholar
  25. Martin, A.D. and Quinn, K.M. (1997). Evaluating theories of West German voting behavior. Typescript. Washington University in St. Louis.Google Scholar
  26. McCulloch, R. and Rossi. P.E. (1994). An exact likelihood analysis of the multinomial probit model. Journal of Econometrics64: 207-240.Google Scholar
  27. McKelvey, R.D. (1986). Covering, dominance and institution-free properties of social choice. American Journal of Political Science30: 283-314.Google Scholar
  28. McKelvey, R.D. and Schofield, N. (1986). Structural instability of the core. Journal of Mathematical Economics15: 179-198.Google Scholar
  29. Osborne, M.J. (1993). Candidate positioning and entry in a political competition. Games and Economic Behavior5: 133-151.Google Scholar
  30. Osborne, M.J. (1995). Spatial models of political competition under plurality rule: A survey of some explanations of the number of candidates and the positions they take. Canadian Journal of Economics28: 261-301.Google Scholar
  31. Poole, K.T. and Rosenthal, H. (1991). Patterns of congressional voting. American Journal of Political Science35: 228-278.Google Scholar
  32. Quinn, K.M., Martin, A.D. and Whitford, A.B. (1996). Explaining voter choice in a multiparty democracy: A look at data from the Netherlands. Typescript. Washington University in St. Louis.Google Scholar
  33. Rabier, J.-R. and Inglehardt, R. (1981). Eurobarometer11. April 1979: The Year of the Child in EuropeAnn Arbor: Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research.Google Scholar
  34. Riker, W. (1962). The theory of political coalitions. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  35. Riker, W.H. (1982). The two-party system and Duverger's Law: An essay in the history of political science. American Political Science Review76: 753-766.Google Scholar
  36. Saari, D. (1996). The generic existence of a core for q-rules. Economic Theory9: 219-260.Google Scholar
  37. Schofield, N. (1985). Social choice and democracy. Heidelberg: Springer-Verlag.Google Scholar
  38. Schofield, N. (1986). Existence of a 'structurally stable’ equilibrium for a non-collegial voting rule. Public Choice51: 267-284.Google Scholar
  39. Schofield, N. (1993). Political competition in multiparty coalition governments. European Journal of Political Research23: 1-33.Google Scholar
  40. Schofield, N. (1995a). Existence of a smooth social choice functor. In W. Barnett, H. Moulin, M. Salles, and N. Schofield (Eds.), Social Choice, Welfare and Ethics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  41. Schofield, N. (1995b). Coalition politics: A formal model and empirical analysis. Journal of Theoretical Politics7: 245-281.Google Scholar
  42. Schofield, N. (1996). The heart of a polity. In N. Schofield (Ed.), Collective decision making: Social choice and political economy. Boston: Kluwer.Google Scholar
  43. Schofield, N. (1997a). Multiparty electoral politics. In D. Mueller (Ed.), Perspectives on public choice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  44. Schofield, N. (1997b). The C1 topology on the space of smooth preference profiles. Social Choice and Welfare(forthcoming).Google Scholar
  45. Schofield, N. and Parks, R. (1996). Existence of a Nash equilibrium in a spatial model of coalition bargaining. Typescript. Washington University in St. Louis.Google Scholar
  46. Schofield, N., Sened, I. and Nixon, D. (1997). Nash equilibrium in multi-party competition with ‘stochastic’ voters. Annals of Operations Research(forthcoming).Google Scholar
  47. Taylor, M. and Laver, M. (1973). Government coalitions in Western Europe. European Journal of Political Research1: 205-248.Google Scholar
  48. Wada, J. and Schofield, N. (1996). Bargaining in the Liberal Democratic Party of Japan. In N. Schofield (Ed.), Collective decision-making: Social choice and political economy. Boston: Kluwer.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Kluwer Academic Publishers 1998

Authors and Affiliations

  • Normal Schofield
    • 1
  • Andrew D. Martin
    • 1
  • Kevin M. Quinn
    • 1
  • Andrew B. Whitford
    • 1
  1. 1.Center in Political EconomyWashington UniversitySt. LouisU.S.A.

Personalised recommendations