Skip to main content
Log in

A theory of the conditional influence of the European Parliament in the cooperation procedure

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

I provide a public choice-based explanation of why the European Parliament is sometimes influential in the cooperation procedure. While a conservative Parliament can use its right of rejections to block a decision effectively whenever there is no consent in the Council, a Parliament in favor of change can successfully use its amendment right in the second reading whenever the constraints have been changed unexpectedly since the adoption of the common position such as to create an amendment win set. Then, the European Parliament can choose its most preferred policy in this set which is supported by the Commission, cannot be changed by the Council and is preferred against the status quo by a qualified majority in the Council.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Arp, H. A. (1992). The European Parliament in European Community environmental policy. Working paper, European University Institute, Florence.

    Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith, D. and Riker, W. (1987). Asymmetric information and the coherence of legislation. American Political Science Review 81: 987-918.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowler, S. and Farrell, D. M. (1995). The organizing of the European Parliament: committees, specialization and co-ordination. British Journal of Political Science 25: 219-243.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bueno de Mesquita, B. and Stokman, F. N. (1994). (Eds.), European Community decision making: Models, applications, and comparisons, New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crombez, C. (1996a). Legislative procedures in the European Community. British Journal of Political Science 26: 199-228.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crombez, C. (1996b). The co-decision procedure in the European Union. manuscript. Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, Belgium.

    Google Scholar 

  • Earnshaw, D. and Judge, D. (1993). The European Parliament and the sweeteners directive: From footnote to inter-institutional conflict. Journal of Common Market Studies 31 (March): 103-116.

    Google Scholar 

  • Enelow, J.M. and Hinich, M. J. (1987).Optimal decision making when the shapes and locations of voter preference curves are unknown. Economia delle Scelte Pubbliche 3 (September): 161-170.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fitzmaurice, J. (1988). An analysis of the European Community’ co-operation procedure. Journal of Common Market Studies 26 (June): 389-400.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garrett, G. (1995). From the Luxembourg compromise to codecision: Decision making in the Europeann Union. Elecoral Studies 14 (3): 289-308.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holzinger, K. (1994) Politik des kleinsten gemeinsamen Nenners? Umweltpolitische Entscheidungsprozesse in der EGam Beispiel der Einführung des Katalysatorautos .Berlin: Edition Sigma.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hubschmid, C. and Moser, P. (1996). The cooperation procedure in the EU: Why was the European Parliament influencial in the decision about car emission standards? Discussion paperEconomics Department at the University of St. Gallen. No. 9602.

  • Jacobs, F. and Corbett, R. (1990). The European Parliament. Harlow: Longman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Judge, D., Earnshaw, D. and Cowan, N. (1994). Ripples or waves: The European Parliament in the European Community policy process. Journal of European Public Policy 1 (1): 27-52.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kapteyn, P.J.G., Verloren van Themaat, P. (1989). Introduction to the law of the European Communities. 2. edition. Deventer: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krehbiel, K. (1991). Information and legislative organization. Ann Arbor: Michigan University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laver, M. and Shepsle, K. A. (1990). Coalitions and cabinet government. American Political Science Review 84: 873-890.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lenz, C. O. (1994). (Ed.) EG-Vertrag: Kommentar. Basel: Helbling und Lichtenhahn.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moser, P. (1996). The European Parliament as a conditional agenda setter: What are the conditions? A critique of Tsebelis (1994). Forthcoming American Political Science Review.

  • Romer, T. and Rosenthal, H. (1978). Political resource allocation, controlled agendas, and the status quo. Public Choice 33 (Winter): 27-43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenthal, H. (1990). The Setter Model. In J. M. Enelow and M. J. Hinich (Eds.), Advances in the spatial theory of voting,199-234. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schneider, G. (1995). The limits of self-reform: Institution-building in the European Union. European Journal of International Relations 1(1): 59-86.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K. A. (1979). Institutional arrangements and equilibrium in multidimensional voting models. American Journal of Political Science 23 (February): 27-59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steunenberg, B. (1994a). Regulatory policymaking in a parliamentary setting. Jahrbuch für Neue Politische Oekonomie 13: 36-57.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steunenberg, B. (1994b). Decision making under different institutional arrangements: Legislation by the European Community. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 150(4): 642-669.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G. (1994). The power of the European Parliament as a conditional agenda setter. American Political Science Review 88 (March): 128-142.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G. (1995a). Decisionmaking inside the European Parliament. In B. Eichengreen, J. Frieden and J. von Hagen (Eds.), Politics and institutions in an integrated Europe,42-64. Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G. (1995b). Will Maastricht reduce the ‘democratic deficit’? APSA Comparative Politics 6 (Winter): 4-6.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G. (1995c). Decision making in political systems: Veto players in presidentialism, parliamentarism, multicameralism and multipartyism. British Journal of Political Science 25: 289-325.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vogel, D. (1995). Trading up: consumers and environmental regulation in a global economy. Harvard: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Von der Groeben, H., Thiesing, J. and Ehlermann, C.-D. (1991). (Eds.)Kommentar zum EWGVertrag. Baden-Baden: Nomos.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. R. (1989). Floor behavior in the U.S. Congress: Committee power under the open rule. American Political Science Review 83 (September); 795-815.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. R. and Marshall, W. (1988). The industrial organization of Congress; or, why legislatures, like firms, are not organized as markets. Journal of Political Economy 96 (1): 132-63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. R. and Moran, M. J. (1983). Bureaucratic discretion or congressional control? Regulatory policymaking by the Federal Trade Commission. Journal of Political Economy 91 (October): 765-800.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wessel, W. (1991). The EC Council: The Community's decisionmaking center. In R. O. Keohane and S. Hoffmann (Eds.), The new European Community: Decisionmaking and institutional change, 133-154. Boulder: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Westlake, M. (1994). The Commission and the Parliament: Partners and rivals in the european policy-making process. London: Butterworth.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Moser, P. A theory of the conditional influence of the European Parliament in the cooperation procedure. Public Choice 91, 333–350 (1997). https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1004996410910

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1004996410910

Keywords

Navigation