Alba, J.W. and Marmorstein, H. (1987), The effects of frequency knowledge on consumer decision making, Journal of Consumer Research14: 14-25.
Google Scholar
Battalio, R., Kagel, J. and Jiranyakul, R. (1990), Testing between alternative models of choice under uncertainty: Some initial results, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty3: 25-50.
Article
Google Scholar
Bell, D.E. (1982), Regret in decision making under uncertainty, Operations Research30: 961-981.
Google Scholar
Einhorn, H.J. and Hogarth, R.M. (1978), Confidence in judgment: persistence in the illusion of validity, Psychological Review85: 396-416.
Google Scholar
Einhorn, H.J. and Hogarth, R.M. (1986), Decision making under ambiguity, Journal of Business59: 5225-5250.
Google Scholar
Estes, W.K. (1976a), The cognitive side of probability learning, Psychological Review83: 37-64.
Google Scholar
Estes, W.K. (1976b), Some functions of probability learning and choice behaviour, in Bower, G.H. (ed), The Psychology of Learning and Motivation, Vol. 10. New York: Academic Press.
Google Scholar
Fishburn, P.C. (1982), Nontransitive measurable utility, Journal of Mathematical Psychology26: 31-67.
Google Scholar
Fishburn, P.C. (1987), Reconsiderations in the theory of choice under uncertainty, Economic Journal97: 825-841.
Google Scholar
Grether, D.M. and Plott, C.R. (1979), Economic theory of choice and the preference reversal phenomenon, American Economic Review69: 623-638.
Google Scholar
Harless, D.W. (1992), Actions versus prospects: the effect of problem representation on regret, American Economic Review82: 634-649.
Google Scholar
Harless, D.W. and Camerer, C.F. (1994), The Predictive utility of generalized expected utility theories, Econometrica62: 1251-1289.
Google Scholar
Hasher, L. and Zacks, R.T. (1984), Automatic processing of fundamental information: the case of frequency of occurrence, American Psychologist39: 1372-1389.
Google Scholar
Hey, J.D. and Orme, C. (1994), Investigating generalizations of expected utility theory using experimental data, Econometrica62: 633-640.
Google Scholar
Humphrey, S.J. (1995), Regret aversion or event-splitting effects? More evidence under risk and uncertainty, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty11: 263-274.
Google Scholar
Humphrey, S.J. (1996), Do anchoring effects underlie event-splitting effects? An experimental test, Economics Letters51: 295-301.
Google Scholar
Kahneman, D. and Tversky, A. (1979), Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk, Econometrica47: 263-291.
Google Scholar
Kisielius, J. and Sternthal, B. (1986), Examining the vividness controversy: an availability-valence interpretation, Journal of Consumer Research12: 418-431.
Google Scholar
Lichtenstein, S. and Slovic, P. (1971), Reversals of preference between bids and choices in gambling decisions, Journal of Experimental Psychology89: 46-55.
Google Scholar
Lichtenstein, S. and Slovic, P. (1973), Response-induced reversals of preferences in gambling: an experimental replication in Las Vegas, Journal of Experimental Psychology101: 16-20.
Google Scholar
Loomes, G. and Sugden, R. (1982), Regret theory: an alternative theory of rational choice under uncertainty, Economic Journal92: 805-824.
Google Scholar
Loomes, G. and Sugden, R. (1987a), Some implications of a more general form of regret theory, Journal of Economic Theory41: 270-287.
Google Scholar
Loomes, G. and Sugden, R. (1987b), Testing for regret and disappointment in choice under uncertainty, Economic Journal97 (supplement): 118-129.
Google Scholar
Loomes, G., Starmer, C. and Sugden R. (1991), Observing violations of transitivity by experimental methods, Econometrica59: 425-439.
Google Scholar
Loomes, G., Starmer, C. and Sugden, R. (1992), Are preferences monotonic? Testing some predictions of regret theory, Economica59: 17-33.
Google Scholar
Luce, R.D. (1959), Individual Choice Behaviour: A Theoretical Analysis. New York: Wiley.
Google Scholar
March, J.G. (1978), Bounded rationality, ambiguity and the engineering of choice, Bell Journal of Economics9: 587-608.
Google Scholar
Reber, A.S. and Millward, R.B. (1968), Event observation in probability learning, Journal of Experimental Psychology77: 317-327.
Google Scholar
Slovic, P. (1972), From Shakespeare to Simon: speculation-and some evidence-about man's ability to process information, Oregon Research Institute Bulletin12 (3).
Starmer, C. (1992), Violations of monotonicity-regret effects or probability processing effects? An experimental test, Economics Research Centre Discussion Paper No.9218, University of East Anglia, Norwich.
Starmer, C. and Sugden, R. (1993), Testing for juxtaposition and event-splitting effects, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty6: 235-254.
Google Scholar
Sugden, R. (1993), An axiomatic foundation for regret theory, Journal of Economic Theory60: 159-178.
Google Scholar
Thaler, R. (1987), The psychology of choice and the assumptions of economics, in Roth, A.E. (ed.), Laboratory Experimentation in Economics: Six Points of View. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Google Scholar
Thurstone, L.L. (1927), A law of comparative judgment, Psychological Review34: 273-286.
Google Scholar
Thurstone, L.L. (1959), TheMeasurement of Values. Chicago: Chicago University Press.
Google Scholar
Tversky, A. and Kahneman, D. (1974), Judgment under uncertainty: heuristics and biases, Science185: 1124-1131.
Google Scholar
Tversky, A. and Kahneman, D. (1992), Advances in prospect theory: cumulative representation of uncertainty, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty5: 297-323.
Google Scholar