De Economist

, Volume 149, Issue 1, pp 33–51 | Cite as

Macroeconomic Consequences of Outsourcing: An Analysis of Growth, Welfare, and Product Variety

  • Henri L.F. De Groot
Article

Abstract

Outsourcing of non-core activities is nowadays a common business strategy. Declining transaction and transportation costs caused by the advent of Information and Communication Technology are a potentially important driving force behind this development. This paper provides a theoretical framework for analysing a firm's incentive to follow such a strategy of outsourcing and its consequences for macroeconomic variables like growth and product variety. We divide production activities into core and non-core activities. Non-core activities can be performed within the firm or can be mediated by the market. We derive conditions under which outsourcing occurs, and under which outsourcing is socially desirable. These conditions do not necessarily coincide. Outsourcing may hence be a profitable strategy for firms, while it is socially suboptimal. Crucial parameters in the model are the relative scale of core versus non-core activities, management costs, transaction costs and love for variety of consumers.

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

REFERENCES

  1. Abraham, K.G. (1990), ‘Restructuring the Employment Relationship: The Growth of Market Mediated Work Arrangements,’ in: K.G. Abraham and R.B. McKersie (eds.), New Developments in the Labor Market, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
  2. Abraham, K.G. and S.K. Taylor (1993), ‘Firms' Use of Outside Contractors: Theory and Evidence,’ NBER Working Paper, No. 4468, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
  3. Audretsch, D.B. (1995), ‘The Innovation, Unemployment and Competitiveness Challenge in Germany,’ CEPR Discussion Paper, No. 1152, London.Google Scholar
  4. Benassy, J.P. (1996), ‘Taste for Variety and Optimum Production Patterns in Monopolistic Competition,’ Economics Letters, 52, pp. 41–47.Google Scholar
  5. Bhagwati, J.N. (1984), ‘Splintering and Disembodiment of Services and Developing Nations,’ World Economy, 7, pp. 133–143.Google Scholar
  6. Broer, D.P. and B.J. Heijdra (1996), ‘The Intergenerational Distribution Effects of the Investment Tax Credit under Monopolistic Competition,’ OCFEB Research Memorandum, No. 9603, Rotterdam.Google Scholar
  7. Dixit, A.K. and J.E. Stiglitz (1977), ‘Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity,’ American Economic Review, 67, pp. 297–308.Google Scholar
  8. Dluhosch, B. (1997), ‘Trade Liberalization, Technological Change, and the Economics of Outsourcing,’ University of Cologne, mimeo.Google Scholar
  9. Eliasson, G. (1992), ‘Business Competence, Organisational Learning and Economic Growth,’ in: F. Scherer and M. Perlman (eds.), Entrepreneurship, Innovation and Economic Growth, University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor.Google Scholar
  10. Feenstra, R.C. and G.H. Hanson (1995), ‘Foreign Investment, Outsourcing and Relative Wages,’ NBER Working Paper, No. 5121, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
  11. Fixler, D.J. and D. Siegel (1999), ‘Outsourcing and Productivity Growth in Services,’ Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 10, pp. 177–194.Google Scholar
  12. Francois, J.F. and K.A. Reinert (1995), ‘The Role of Services in the Structure of Production and Trade: Stylized Facts from a Cross-Country Analysis,’ CEPR Discussion Paper, No. 1228, London.Google Scholar
  13. Freeman, C. and L. Soete (1994), Work for All or Mass Unemployment? Computerised Technical Change into the Twenty-First Century, Pinter Publishers, London.Google Scholar
  14. Gordon, D.M. (1996), Fat and Mean, Free Press, New York.Google Scholar
  15. Groot, H.L.F. de (1998), Economic Growth, Sectoral Structure and Unemployment, CentER Dissertation Series, No. 43, Tilburg.Google Scholar
  16. Groot, H.L.F. de and R. Nahuis (1997), ‘Optimal Product Variety, Scale Effects and Growth,’ CentER Discussion Paper, No. 9754, Tilburg.Google Scholar
  17. Kelley, M. (1997), ‘The Dynamics of Smithian Growth,’ Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, pp. 939–964.Google Scholar
  18. Lovio, R. (1994), ‘Evolution of Firm Communities in New Industries: The Case of the Finnish Electronics Industry,’ Helsinki School of Economics, Helsinki.Google Scholar
  19. Pavitt, K. (1986), ‘Chips and Trajectories: How Does the Semi-Conductor Influence the Direction of Technical Change?,’ in: R. Macleod (ed.), Technology and the Human Prospect, Pinter Publishers, London.Google Scholar
  20. Postner, H.H. (1990), ‘The Contracting-out Problem in Service Sector Analysis: Choice of Statistical Unit,’ Review of Income and Wealth, 36, pp. 177–186.Google Scholar
  21. Raa, T. ten and E.N. Wolff (2000), ‘Outsourcing of Services and the Productivity Recovery in US Manufacturing in the 1980s and 1990s,’ CentER Discussion Paper, 2000-32, Tilburg.Google Scholar
  22. Simonetti, R. (1993), ‘The Long-Run Performance of Large Firms: A Study of Changes in the ‘Fortune’ List 1964-1988,’ University of Sussex, SPRU, mimeo.Google Scholar
  23. Smulders, S. and Th.C.M.J. van de Klundert (1995), ‘Imperfect Competition, Concentration and Growth with Firm Specific Knowledge,’ European Economic Review, 39, pp. 139–160.Google Scholar
  24. Williamson, O.E. (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, Free Press, New York.Google Scholar
  25. Williamson, O.E. (1998), ‘Transaction Cost Economics: How it Works; Where it is Headed,’ De Economist, 146, pp. 23–58.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Kluwer Academic Publishers 2001

Authors and Affiliations

  • Henri L.F. De Groot

There are no affiliations available

Personalised recommendations