Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Can Openness Help Make a Miracle?

  • Published:
De Economist Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Several empirical studies indicate that there is a positive relationship between openness to international trade and growth. Lucas (1988) argues that this relationship poses a paradox for neo-classical theory because trade liberalisation produces only limited level effects, not long-run growth effects, in neo-classical growth models. This paper attempts to resolve Lucas’ paradox by adding production sectors to the basic one-sector Solow model. This paper demonstrates that these multi-sector models are consistent with the empirical links between openness and growth. These models also blur the traditional distinctions between exogenous and endogenous growth theory. As a result, they substantially complicate the task of discriminating between exogenous and endogenous growth episodes in empirical data.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

REFERENCES

  • Arrow, K.J., H.B. Chenery, B.S. Minhas, and R.M. Solow (1961), ‘Capital-Labor Substitution and Economic Efficiency,’ Review of Economics and Statistics, 43 (3), August, pp. 225-250.

    Google Scholar 

  • Backus, D., P.J. Kehoe, and T. Kehoe (1990), ‘In Search of Scale Effects in Trade and Growth’, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis working paper nr. 451, Minneapolis.

  • Baldwin, R.E. and E. Seghezza (1996), ‘Trade-Induced Investment-Led Growth', CEPR discussion paper nr. 1420, London.

  • Barro, R.J. and X. Sala-i-Martin (1995), Economic Growth, New York, McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R.J. and X. Sala-i-Martin (1997), ‘Technological Diffusion, Convergence and Growth,’ Journal of Economic Growth, 2, pp. 1-26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W.J., R.R. Nelson, and E.N. Wolff (eds) (1994), Convergence of Productivity: Cross-National Studies and Historical Evidence, New York, Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ben-David, D. (1993), ‘Equalizing Exchange: Trade Liberalization and Income Convergence,’ Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108 (3), August, pp. 653-679.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib, J. and M.M. Spiegel (1994), ‘The Role of Human Capital in Economic Development: Evidence from Aggregate Cross-Country Data,’ Journal of Monetary Economics, 34 (2), pp. 143-173.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhagwati, J.N. (1984), ‘Why are Services Cheaper in the Poor Countries?,’ Economic Journal, 94, June, pp. 279-286.

  • Chenary, H., S. Robinson, and M. Syrquin (1986), Industrialization and Growth, Oxford, The World Bank and Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chow, P.C.Y. and M.H. Kellman (1993), Trade-The Engine of Growth in East Asia, New York, Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deardorff, A.V. (1974), ‘Factor Proportions and Comparative Advantage in the Long Run: Comment,’ Journal of Political Economy, 82 (4), pp. 829-833.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dollar, D. (1992), ‘Outward-Oriented Developing Economies Really Do Grow More Rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs, 1976-1985,’ Economic Development and Cultural Change, 40 (3), pp. 523-544.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edwards, S. (1998), ‘Openness, Productivity and Growth: What Do we Really Know?,’ Economic Journal, 108 (447), pp. 383-398.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein, M. and C. Horioka (1980), ‘Domestic Saving and International Capital Flows,’ Economic Journal, 90, pp. 314-328.

    Google Scholar 

  • Findlay, R. (1970), ‘Factor Proportions and Comparative Advantage in the Long Run,’ Journal of Political Economy, 78 (1), pp. 27-34.

    Google Scholar 

  • Findlay, R. (1995), Factor Proportions, Trade and Growth, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frankel, J.A. (1991), ‘Quantifying International Capital Mobility in the 1980s,’ in: D. Bernheim and J. Shoven (eds), National Saving and Economic Performance, Chicago, University of Chicago Press, pp. 227-260.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O. (1996), ‘Convergence? Inferences from Theoretical Models,’ Economic Journal, 106, July, pp. 1056-1069.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, R.A. (1961), ‘Differential Changes in the Prices of Consumers' and Capital Goods,’ American Economic Review, 51, pp. 937-957.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grandville, Olivier de La (1989), ‘In Quest of the Slutsky Diamond,’ American Economic Review, 79 (3), pp. 468-481.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G.M. and E. Helpman (1991), Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamermesh, D.S. (1986), ‘The Demand for Labour in the Long Run,’ in: O. Ashenfelter and R. Layard (eds), Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 1, Amsterdam, North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Havrylyshyn, O. (1990), ‘Trade Policy and Productivity Gains in Developing Countries: A Survey of the Literature,’ The World Bank Research Observer, 5, pp. 1-24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Inada, K.-I. (1963), ‘On a Two-Sector Model of Economic Growth: Comments and a Generalization,’ Review of Economic Studies, 30, pp. 119-127.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, C.I. (1995), ‘Times Series Tests of Endogenous Growth Models,’ Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110 (2), pp. 495-525.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, R.W. (1965), ‘The Structure of Simple General Equilibrium Models,’ Journal of Political Economy, 73 (6), pp. 557-572.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim, J.-I. and L. Lau (1994), ‘The Sources of Ecnomic Growth of the East Asian Newly Industrialised Countries,’ Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 8, pp. 235-271.

    Google Scholar 

  • Komiya, R. (1967), ‘Non-traded Goods and the Pure Theory of International Trade,’ International Economic Review, 8 (2), June, pp. 132-152.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kravis, I.B. and R.E. Lipsey (1983), ‘Toward an Explanation of National Price Levels,’ Princeton Studies in International Finance nr. 52, November, Princeton, N.J.

  • Krugman, P. (1987), ‘The Narrow Moving Band, the Dutch Disease, and the Competitive Consequences of Mrs Thatcher: Notes on Trade in the Presence of Dynamic Scale Economies,’ Journal of Development Economics, 27, pp. 41-55.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P.R. (1994), ‘The Myth of Asia's Miracle,’ Foreign Affairs, November/December, pp. 62-78.

  • Laux-Meiselbach, W. (1989), ‘A Note on Import Substitution Versus Export Promotion as Strategies for Development,’ Kyklos, 42 (2), pp. 219-229.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lawrence, R.Z. and D.E. Weinstein (1999), ‘Trade and Growth: Import-led or Export-led? Evidence from Japan and Korea’, NBER working paper nr. 7264, Cambridge, MA.

  • Levine, R. and D. Renelt (1992), ‘A Sensitivity Analysis of Cross-Country Growth Regressions,’ American Economic Review, 82 (4), pp. 942-963.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lipsey, R.E., I.B. Kravis, and R.A. Roldan (1982), ‘Do Multinational Firms Adapt Factor Proportions to Relative Factor Prices?,’ in: A.O. Krueger, (ed.), Trade and Employment in Developing Countries: 2 Factor Supply and Substitution, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R.E. (1988), ‘On the Mechanics of Economic Development,’ Journal of Monetary Economics, 22 (1), pp. 3-42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R.E. (1989), ‘Making a Miracle,’ Econometrica, 61, pp. 251-272.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meier, G.M. (1989), Leading Issues in Economic Development, New York, Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morawetz, D. (1976), ‘Elasticities of Substitution in Industry: What Do We Learn From Econometric Estimates?,’ World Development, 4 (1), pp. 11-15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld, M. and K. Rogoff (1996), Foundations of International Macroeconomics, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pack, H. (1994), ‘Endogenous Growth Theory: Intellectual Appeal and Empirical Shortcomings,’ Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8 (1), Winter, pp. 55-72.

    Google Scholar 

  • Panagariya, A., S. Shah, and D. Mishra (1996), ‘Demand Elasticities in International Trade: Are They Really Low?,’ World Bank discussion paper nr. 1712, Washington, D.C.

  • Riedel, J. (1988), ‘The Demand for Exports of Manufactures: Estimates for Hong Kong,’ Economic Journal, 98, March, pp. 138-148.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riedel, J. (1989), ‘The Demand for Exports of Manufactures: Estimates for Hong Kong: A Rejoinder,’ Economic Journal, 99, pp. 467-470.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rivera-Batiz, L. and P. Romer (1991), ‘Economic Integration and Endogenous Growth,’ Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106 (2), pp. 531-555.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodriguez, F. and D. Rodrik (1999), ‘Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A Skeptic's Guide to the Cross-National Evidence,’ University of Maryland and Kennedy School of Government, mimeo.

  • Rodrik, D. (1995), ‘Trade Strategy, Investment and Exports: Another Look at East Asia,’ CEPR discussion paper nr. 1305, London.

  • Romer, P. (1986), ‘Increasing Returns and Long Run Growth,’ Journal of Political Economy, 94 (5), pp. 1002-1037.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. (1990), ‘Endogenous Technological Change,’ Journal of Political Economy, 98 (5) part 2, pp. 71-102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sachs, J.D. and A. Warner (1995), ‘Economic Reform and the Process of Global Integration,’ Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, (1), pp. 1-95, 108-118.

  • Sato, R. (1969), ‘Stability Conditions in Two-Sector Models of Economic Growth,’ Journal of Economic Theory, 1, pp. 107-117.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R.M. (1956), ‘A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth,’ Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70, February, pp. 65-94.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R.M. (1961), ‘Note on Uzawa's Two-Sector Model of Economic Growth,’ Review of Economic Studies, 29, pp. 48-50.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R.M. (1994), ‘Perspectives on Growth Theory,’ Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8 (1), Winter, pp. 45-54.

    Google Scholar 

  • Summers, R., A. Heston, B. Aten, and D.A. Nuxoll (1995), Penn World Table, Mark 5.6a, Cambridge, MA, NBER Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Uzawa, H. (1961), ‘On a Two-Sector Model of Economic Growth: A Comparative Statics Analysis,’ Review of Economic Studies, 29, pp. 40-47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Uzawa, H. (1963), ‘On a Two-Sector Model of Economic Growth II,’ Review of Economic Studies, 30, pp. 105-118.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ventura, J. (1997), ‘Growth and Interdependence,’ Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112 (1), pp. 57-84.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weinhold, D. and J.E. Rauch (1999), ‘Openness, Specialization and Productivity Growth in Less Developed Countries,’ Canadian Journal of Economics, 32 (4), pp. 1009-1027.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, L.J. (1978), ‘The Evidence on Appropriate Factor Proportions for Manufacturing in Less Developed Countries: A Survey,’ Economic Development and Cultural Change, 27 (1), pp. 27-59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wood, A. (1995), ‘How Trade Hurt Unskilled Workers,’ Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9 (3), Summer, pp. 57-80.

    Google Scholar 

  • The World Bank (1993), The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy, Washington, D.C., Oxford University Press for the World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • The World Bank (1998), World Development Report 1998, New York, Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, A. (1991), ‘Learning by Doing and the Dynamic Effects of International Trade,’ Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106 (2), pp. 369-406.

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, A. (1992), ‘A Tale of Two Cities: Factor Accumulation and Technical Change in Hong Kong and Singapore,’ NBER Macroeconomics Annual, pp. 13-54.

  • Young, A. (1993), ‘Lessons from the East Asian NICS: A contrarian view,’ European Economic Review, 38, pp. 964-973.

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, A. (1995), ‘The Tyranny of Numbers: Confronting the Statistical Realities of the East Asian Growth Experience,’ Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110 (3), August, pp. 641-680.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yuhn, Ky-hyang (1991), ‘Economic Growth, Technical Change Biases, and the Elasticity of Substitution: A Test of the de La Grandville Hypothesis,’ Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 73, pp. 340-346.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

House, B. Can Openness Help Make a Miracle?. De Economist 148, 167–203 (2000). https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1004061128422

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1004061128422

Navigation