Agriculture and Human Values

, Volume 15, Issue 4, pp 347–360 | Cite as

Incentives and informal institutions: Gender and the management of water

  • Frances Cleaver
Article

Abstract

In this paper I consider thecontribution that theories about common propertyresource management and policies relating toparticipation can make to our understanding ofcommunal water resource management. Common totheoretical and policy approaches are the ideas thatincentives are important in defining the problem ofcollective action and that institutions apparentlyoffer a solution to it. The gendered dynamics ofincentives and institutions are explored. This paperbriefly outlines theoretical approaches toinstitutions as solutions to collective actionproblems and indicates the linkages with policiesregarding participation in water resource management.It suggests that, whilst offering considerableinsights, such approaches are limited and may resultin policy prescriptions that do little to involve orempower women. In particular, I argue that themodeling of incentives is impoverished in itseconomism and its abstraction of the individual froma life world. I suggest that the conceptualization ofinstitutions is primarily an organizational one,which, whilst alluding to the role of norms,practices, and conventions, focuses primarily onformal manifestations of collective action; contracts,committees, and meetings. Where women‘s participationis concerned, I illustrate that incentives tocooperative may be devised from reproductive concernsand the minor exigencies of daily life (as well asfrom productive concerns) and that alternative modelsof institutions may better reflect the way in whichdecisions are made and implemented within a socialcontext.

Incentives Informal institutions Policy and organizations 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Berkes, F. (1989). Common Property Resources: Ecology and Community Based Sustainable Development. London: Belhaven Press.Google Scholar
  2. Berkes, F. and M. Taghi Farvar (1989). “Introduction and overview,” in F. Berkes (ed.), Common Property Resources: Ecology and Community Based Sustainable Development. London: Belhaven Press.Google Scholar
  3. Berry, S. (1989). “Social institutions and access to resources,” Africa(1): 41–55.Google Scholar
  4. Brett, E. A. (1996). “The participatory principle in development projects: The costs and benefits of cooperation,” Public Administration and Development16: 5–19.Google Scholar
  5. Bromley, D. W. (ed.) (1992). Making the Commons Work: Theory Practice and Policy. San Francisco: ICS.Google Scholar
  6. Chambers. R. (1983). Rural Development. Putting the Last First.London: Longman.Google Scholar
  7. Ciriacy-Wantrop, S. A. and R. C. Bishop (1975). “Common Property as a Concept in Natural Resources Policy,” Natural Resources Journal(October) 15: 713–727.Google Scholar
  8. Cleaver, F. (1991). “Maintenance of rural water supplies in Zimbabwe,” Waterlines9(4): 23–26.Google Scholar
  9. Cleaver, F. (1994). “Community management, A Discussion Paper,” Prepared for UNCHS Community Management Programme Review Meeting, Nairobi, 20–24 March, University of Bradford.Google Scholar
  10. Cleaver, F. and D. Elson (1995). Women and Water Resources: Continued Marginalisation and New Policies, Gatekeeper Series No. 49, London: International Institute for Environment and Development.Google Scholar
  11. Cleaver, F. and I. Lomas (1996). “The 5% ‘rule’: Fact or fiction?” Development Policy Review14(2): 173–183.Google Scholar
  12. DAC (1994). Gender and Water Resources Management: Note by the DAC Expert Group on Women in Development. Paris; Organisation of Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD).Google Scholar
  13. DANIDA, (1992). Danish Sector Policies. Water Supply and Sanitation. Copenhagen: Ministry of Foreign Affairs.Google Scholar
  14. Davis, S. (1996). “Implementing gender policy in the water and sanitation sector,” Natural Resources Forum20(3): 189–197.Google Scholar
  15. Douglas, M. (1987). How Institutions Think. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
  16. Folbre, N. (1996). “Engendering economics: New perspectives on women, work and demographic change,” in M. Bruno and B. Pleskovic (eds.), Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics 1995. Washington, DC: The World Bank.Google Scholar
  17. Giddens, A. (1984). The Constitution of Society: Outline of the Theory of Structuration. Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
  18. Granovetter, M. (1992). “Economic action and social structures: The problem of embeddedness,” in M. Granovetter and R. Swedberg (eds.), The Sociology of Economic Life. Oxford: Westview Press.Google Scholar
  19. Kabeer, N. (1994). Reversed Realities: Gender Hierarchies in Development Thought. London: Verso.Google Scholar
  20. Klumper, A. (1995). “Analysis of water supply projects in practice,” in Development Projects: Issues for the 1990s, Papers from the 25th Anniversary Conference 7th April, DPPC, University of Bradford.Google Scholar
  21. March, J. G. and H. A. Simon (1958). Organisations. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
  22. Mayoux, L. (1995). “Beyond naivety: Women, gender inequality and participatory development,” Development and Change26: 235–258.Google Scholar
  23. Moser, C. (1989). “Gender planning in the Third World. meeting practical and strategic gender meeds,” World Development17(11): 1799–1825.Google Scholar
  24. Nabli, M. and U. Nugent (1989). “The new institutional economics and its applicability to development,” World Development17(9): 1333–1347.Google Scholar
  25. Najlis, P. and A. Edwards (1991). “The international drinking water supply and sanitation decade in retrospect and the implications for the future,” Natural Resources Forum15(2): 110–117.Google Scholar
  26. Narayan, D. (1995). “The contribution of people's participation. Evidence from 121 rural water supply projects,” ESD Occasional Paper Series No. 1, TheWorld Bank, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
  27. Nelson, R. (1995). “Recent evolutionary theorising about economic change,” Journal of Economic Literature(March) XXXIII: 48–90.Google Scholar
  28. Oakerson, R. J. (1992). “Analyzing the commons: A framework,” in D. W. Bromley (ed.), Making the Commons Work: Theory and Practice and Policy, Chapter 3 (pp. 41–59). San Francisco: ICS Press.Google Scholar
  29. Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  30. Ostrom, E. and R. Gardner (1993). “Coping with asymmetries in the commons: Self governing irrigation systems can work,” Economic Perspectives7(4): 93–112.Google Scholar
  31. Ostrom, E., L. Schroeder, and S. Wynne (1993). Institutional Incentives and Sustainable Development: Infrastructure Policies in Perspectives. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.Google Scholar
  32. Papanek, H. (1990). “To each less than she needs, from each more than she can do: Allocations, entitlements and value,” in I. Tinker (ed.), Persistent Inequalities(pp. 162–184). Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  33. Rocheleau, D. (1995). “Gendered resource mapping,” in R. Slocum, L. Wichhart, D. Rocheleau, and B. Thomas-Slayter (eds.), Power Process and Participation: Tools for Change. London: IT Publications.Google Scholar
  34. Seabright, P. (1993). “Managing local Commons: Theoretical issues in incentive design,” Journal of Economic Perspectives17(4): 113–134.Google Scholar
  35. SDC (1994). Sector Policy in Water Supply and Sanitation. Berne: Swiss Development Cooperation.Google Scholar
  36. Simon, H. A. (1976). Administrative Behaviour. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  37. Simon, H. A. (1991). “Organisations and markets,” Journal of Economic Perspectives(Spring) 5(2): 25–44.Google Scholar
  38. Slocum, P., L. Wichhart, D. Rocheleau, and B. Thomas-Slayter (1995). Power, Process and Participation: Tools for Change. London: IT Publications.Google Scholar
  39. UNCED (1992). United Nations Conference on Environment and Development, Agenda 21.Google Scholar
  40. UNDP (1990). Background Papers and the New Delhi Statement, Global Consultation on Safe Water and Sanitation for the 1990s. New Delhi, India, UNDP, New York.Google Scholar
  41. UNICEF (1986). Evaluation of the UNICEF Assisted Well Digging Programme in Matabeleland. Evaluation Report, Harare, Zimbabwe.Google Scholar
  42. UNICEF (1995). UNICEF Strategies in Water and Environmental Sanitation. UNICEF, New York.Google Scholar
  43. Uphoff, N. (1992). Local Institutions and Participation for Sustainable Development, Gatekeepers Series No. 31, International Institute for Environment and Development, London.Google Scholar
  44. Uphoff, N. (1996). Learning from Gal Oya. Possibilities for Participatory Development and Post-Newtonian Social Science. London: IT Publications.Google Scholar
  45. Wade, R. (1986). “Common property resource management,” in Proceedings of the Conference on Common Property Resource Management. Washington, DC: National Academy Press.Google Scholar
  46. Wade, R. (1988). Village Republics: Economic Conditions for Collective Action in South India. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  47. Wakeman, W., S. Davis, C. van Wijk, and A. Naithani (1996). Sourcebook for Gender Issues at the Policy Level in the Water and Sanitation Sector. Washington, DC: The World Bank.Google Scholar
  48. World Bank (1993). “Water resources management: A World Bank policy paper.” Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
  49. Woronuik, B. (1994). “Against the current: women mainstreaming and water in UNICEF,” in Gender and Water Resources Management: Lessons Learnt and Strategies for the Future. Stockholm: SIDA.Google Scholar
  50. Yacoob, M. and J. Walker (1991). “Community management in water supply and sanitation projects, costs and implications,” AQUA40(1): 30–34.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Kluwer Academic Publishers 1998

Authors and Affiliations

  • Frances Cleaver
    • 1
  1. 1.Development and Project Planning CentreUniversity of BradfordBradfordUK

Personalised recommendations