Advertisement

Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade

, Volume 4, Issue 3, pp 223–238 | Cite as

Mobile Number Portability

  • Stefan Buehler
  • Justus Haucap
Article

Abstract

This paper examines the consequences of introducing mobile number portability (MNP). We show that if the sole effect of introducing MNP is the abolishment of switching costs, MNP unambiguously benefits mobile customers. However, if MNP also causes consumer ignorance, as telephone numbers no longer identify networks, mobile operators will increase termination charges, with ambiguous net effect on the surplus of mobile customers. We examine how extensions such as MNP based on call-forwarding, termination fee regulation, and alternative means of carrier identification affect these findings and discuss policy implications.

number portability switching costs telecommunications network competition 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Aoki, R. and Small, J., “The economics of number portability: switching costs and two-part tariffs,” Working paper, University of Auckland, November 1999.Google Scholar
  2. Armstrong, M., “Network interconnection in telecommunications,” Econ. J., vol. 108, pp. 545–564, 1998.Google Scholar
  3. European Commission, Eighth Report from the Commission on the Implementation of the Telecommunications Regulatory Package, COM(2002) 695, Brussels, December 2002.Google Scholar
  4. Gans, J.S. and King, S.P., “Mobile network competition, customer ignorance and fixed-to-mobile call prices,” Inform. Econ. Policy, vol. 12, pp. 301–327, 2000.Google Scholar
  5. Gans, J.S., King, S.P., and Woodbridge, G., “Numbers to the people: Regulation, ownership, and local number portability,” Inform. Econ. Policy, vol. 13, pp. 167–180, 2001.Google Scholar
  6. Haucap, J., “Telephone number allocation: a property rights approach,” Euro. J. Law Econ., vol. 15, pp. 91–109, 2003.Google Scholar
  7. INTUG, “Mobile number portability,” International Telecommunications User Group (INTUG), [www. intug.net/mnp], 2003.Google Scholar
  8. Laffont, J.J., Rey, P., and Tirole, J., “Network competition I: Overview and nondiscriminatory pricing,” RAND J. Econ., vol. 29, pp. 1–37, 1998.Google Scholar
  9. Laffont, J.J., and Tirole, J., Competition in Telecommunications. MIT Press: Cambridge, MA, 2000.Google Scholar
  10. NERA/Smith, “Feasibility Study and Cost Benefit Analysis of Number Portability for Mobile Services in Hong Kong, Final Report to OFTA,” NERA/Smith: London, May 1998.Google Scholar
  11. Oftel, “Economic evaluation of number portability in the U.K. mobile telephony market,” Oftel: London, July 1997.Google Scholar
  12. Ovum, “Mobile Numbering and Number Portability in Ireland,” A Report to the ODTR, Ovum: London, October 2000.Google Scholar
  13. Reinke, T.H., “Local number portability and local loop competition,” Telecommunications Policy, vol. 22 no. 1, pp. 73–87, 1998.Google Scholar
  14. Schwarz-Schilling, C. and Stumpf, U., “NetzbetreiberportabilitaÈt im Mobilfunkmarkt: Auswirkungen auf Wettbewerb und Verbraucherinteressen,” Discussion Paper No. 199, WIK: Bad Honnef, December 1999.Google Scholar
  15. Wright, J., “Access pricing under competition: an application to cellular networks,” J. Ind. Econ., vol. 50, pp. 289–315, 2002.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Kluwer Academic Publishers 2004

Authors and Affiliations

  • Stefan Buehler
    • 1
  • Justus Haucap
    • 2
  1. 1.Socioeconomic InstituteUniversity of ZurichZurichSwitzerland
  2. 2.Department of EconomicsRuhr-University of Bochum, Universitätsstr. 150, GC3/62BochumGermany

Personalised recommendations