Advertisement

Sociological Forum

, Volume 12, Issue 1, pp 103–115 | Cite as

Simulation Games in Theory Development

  • Scott L. Feld
Article

Abstract

Mathematics provides a set of tools and a language by which sociologists can precisely develop and express an abstract theory of society. Simulation games provide relatively limited and controlled contexts in which qualitative observations may suggest insights upon which to build systematic quantitative social theory. James Coleman was one of the strongest advocates for the use of simulation games in developing and communicating social theory; his Democracy game was a valuable tool in the development of his theory of collective action. In this paper, I provide an extended example of the use of observations of simulation games. My observations of two different games suggested ways to reconsider and revise certain aspects of rational choice theory. Building upon Herbert A. Simon's ([1957] Models of Man, Social and Rational: Mathematical Essays on Rational Human Behavior in a Social Setting, New York: Wiley) and John W. Thibaut and Harold H. Kelley's ([1959] The Social Psychology of Groups, New York: Wiley) theories of rationality in the context of incomplete information, my observations suggested that “frustration behavior” may be a rational response to the failure to meet expectations.

simulation games rational choice frustration expectation emotions 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

REFERENCES

  1. American College Dictionary 1969 New York: Random HouseGoogle Scholar
  2. Axelrod, Robert M 1984 The Evolution of Cooperation. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
  3. Coleman, James S. 1966 Democracy: The Workings of the Legislative Process. New York: Western.Google Scholar
  4. 1973 The Mathematics of Collective Action. Chicago: Aldine.Google Scholar
  5. 1989 “Simulation games and the development of social theory.” Simulation and Games 20:144–164.Google Scholar
  6. 1990 Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  7. Eckstein, Harry 1991 “Rationality and frustration in political behavior.” In Kristen Renwick Monroe (ed.), The Economic Approach to Politics: A Critical Reassessment of the Theory of Rational Action: 74–93. New York: Harper Collins.Google Scholar
  8. Frank, Robert H. 1988 Passions Within Reason: The Strategic Role of the Emotions. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
  9. Greenblat, Cathy S., and Richard D. Duke 1981 Principles and Practices of Gaming-Simulation. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.Google Scholar
  10. Hoffman, Therese Lemire, and Susan Dempsey Reif 1978 Into Aging: A Simulation Game. Thorofare, NJ: C. B. Slack.Google Scholar
  11. Inbar, Michael, and Clarice S. Stoll 1972 Simulation and Gaming in Social Science. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
  12. Maier, N. 1961 Frustration: The Study of Behavior Without a Goal. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
  13. Raser, John R. 1969 Simulation and Society. Boston: Allyn and Bacon.Google Scholar
  14. Shirts, R. Gary 1969 Starpower. Simile II. P. O. Box 910 Del Mar, CA 92014.Google Scholar
  15. Simon, Herbert A. 1957 Models of Man, Social and Rational: Mathematical Essays on Rational Human Behavior in a Social Setting. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
  16. Thibaut, John W., and Harold H. Kelley 1959 The Social Psychology of Groups. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Plenum Publishing Corporation 1997

Authors and Affiliations

  • Scott L. Feld
    • 1
  1. 1.Department of SociologyLouisiana State UniversityBaton Rouge

Personalised recommendations