Computational & Mathematical Organization Theory

, Volume 4, Issue 4, pp 373–404 | Cite as

A Bayesian Model of Panic in Belief

  • Carter Butts
Article

Abstract

One common principle in the study of belief is what has been called the “consensual validation of reality”: the idea that persons in highly inbred social networks alter their beliefs regarding the external world by repeated interaction with each other rather than by direct observation. This notion accounts for phenomena such as panics, in which a substantial number of actors in a given population suddenly converge to (typically unsubstantiated) beliefs. In this paper, a Bayesian conditional probability model will be used to explore the conditions necessary for such outcomes, and alternative results will be likewise documented. Finally, suggestions for operationalization of the Bayesian model in experimental research will be given, along with some implications of the theory for common phenomena such as the propagation of ideas by media sources, organizational rumors, and polarization of group opinion.

panic belief social influence social networks Bayesian updating 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Aiken, M. and G. Hage (1968), “Organizational Interdependency and Intra-Organizational Structure,” American Sociological Review, 33(1).Google Scholar
  2. Anderson, N.H. (1959), “Test of a Model for Opinion Change,” Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology, 59, 371-381.Google Scholar
  3. Anderson, N.H. (1964), “Linear Models for Responses Measured on a Continuous Scale,” Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 1, 121-142.Google Scholar
  4. Anderson, N.H. (1971), “Integration Theory and Attitude Change,” Psychological Review, 79, 171-206.Google Scholar
  5. Asch, S. (1952), Social Psychology. Prentice Hall, NJ.Google Scholar
  6. Banerjee, A.V. (1992), “A Simple Model of Herd Behavior,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(3), 797-817.Google Scholar
  7. Bar-Hillel, M. (1980), “The Base Rate Fallacy in Probability Judgments,” Acta Psychologia, 44, 211-233.Google Scholar
  8. Baron, R., S. Hoppe, C.F. Kao, B. Brunsman, B. Linneweh, and D. Rogers (1996a), “Social Corroboration and Opinion Extremity,” Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 32, 537-560.Google Scholar
  9. Baron, R., J. Vandello, and B. Brunsman (1996b), “The Forgotten Variable in Conformity Research: Impact of Task Performance on Social Influence,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 71(5), 915-927.Google Scholar
  10. Bikhchandani, S., D. Hirshleifer, and I. Welch (1992), “A Theory of Fashion, Custom, and Cultural Change,” Journal of Political Economy, 100(5), 992-1026.Google Scholar
  11. Brass, D. (1984), “Being in the Right Place: A Structural Analysis of Individual Influence in an Organization,” Administrative Science Quarterly, 29.Google Scholar
  12. Bulgatz, J. (1992), Ponzi Schemes, Invaders from Mars and More Extraordinary Popular Delusions. Harmony Books, New York.Google Scholar
  13. Burt, R. (1987), “Social Contagion and Innovation: Cohesion Versus Structural Equivalence,” American Journal of Sociology, 92, 1287-1335.Google Scholar
  14. Burt, R. (1992), Structural Holes: The Social Structure of Competition. Harvard University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
  15. Carley, K. (1990a), “Group Stability: A Socio-Cognitive Approach,” Advances in Group Processes, 7.Google Scholar
  16. Carley, K. (1990b), “On the Persistence of Beliefs, ” Working Paper, Department of Social and Decision Sciences, Carnegie Mellon University.Google Scholar
  17. Coleman, J. (1990), Foundations of Social Theory. Harvard University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
  18. Dawes, R. (1988), Rational Choice in an Uncertain World. Harcourt Brace, Fort Worth.Google Scholar
  19. Degroot, M. (1989), Probability and Statistics(2nd edition). Addison-Wesley, MA.Google Scholar
  20. Deutsch, M. and H.B. Gerard (1955), “A Study of Normative and Informational Social Influences upon Individual Judgment,” Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology, 51(3), 629-636.Google Scholar
  21. DiMaggio, P. and W. Powell (1983), “The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields,” American Sociological Review, 48, 147-160.Google Scholar
  22. Erikson, K. (1966), Wayward Puritans: A Study in the Sociology of Deviance. Wiley, New York.Google Scholar
  23. Fink, E. (1996), “Dynamic Social Impact Theory and the Study of Human Communication,” Journal of Communication, 46(4), 5-12.Google Scholar
  24. Friedkin, N. and K. Cook (1991), “Peer Group Influence,” Sociological Methods and Research, 19, 122-143.Google Scholar
  25. Friedland, R. and R.R. Alford (1991), “Bringing Society Back in: Symbols, Practices and Institutional Contradictions,” in Powell and DiMaggio (Eds.) The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 232-263.Google Scholar
  26. Galaskiewicz, J. and R. Burt (1991), “Interorganization Contagion in Corporate Philanthropy,” Administrative Science Quarterly, 36, 88-105.Google Scholar
  27. Galbraith, J. (1973), Designing Complex Organizations. Addison-Wesley, Reading, MA.Google Scholar
  28. Goel, P. and N.S. Iyengar (Eds.) (1992), Bayesian Analysis in Statistics and Econometrics. Lecture Notes in Statistics, 75, Springer-Verlag, New York.Google Scholar
  29. Goode, E. and N. Ben-Yehuda (1994), “Moral Panics: Culture, Politics, and Social Construction,” Annual Review of Sociology, 20, 149-171.Google Scholar
  30. Granovetter, M. (1982), “The Strength of Weak Ties: A Network Theory Revisited,” in Marsden and Lin (Eds.) 1982.Google Scholar
  31. Granovetter, M. (1985), “Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness,” American Journal of Sociology, 91, 481-515.Google Scholar
  32. Kahneman, D., P. Slovic, and A. Tversky (Eds.) (1982), Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
  33. Kahneman, D. and A. Tversky (1979), “Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk,” Econometrica, 47, 263-291.Google Scholar
  34. Knoke, D. and J.H. Kuklinski (1982), “Network Analysis,” Quantitative Applications in the Social Sciences, J. Sullivan and R. Niemi (Eds.), Vol. 28, Beverly Hills: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
  35. Krackhardt, D. (1996), “Organizational Viscosity and the Diffusion of Controversial Innovations,” Journal of Mathematical Sociology, in press.Google Scholar
  36. Latané, B. (1981), “The Psychology of Social Impact,” American Psychologist, 56(4), 343-356.Google Scholar
  37. Latané, B. and M.J. Bourgeois (1996), “Experimental Evidence for Dynamic Social Impact: The Emergence of Subcultures in Electronic Groups,” Journal of Communication, 46, 35-47.Google Scholar
  38. Latané, B. and T. L'Herrou (1996), “Spatial Clustering in the Conformity Game: Dynamic Social Impact in Electronic Groups,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 70(6), 1218-1230.Google Scholar
  39. Latané, B. and A. Nowak (1994), “Measuring Emergent Social Phenomena: Dynamism, Polarization, and Clustering as Order Parameters of Social Systems,” Behavioral Science, 39, 1-24.Google Scholar
  40. Lux, T. (1995), “Herd Behaviour, Bubbles and Crashes,” The Economic Journal, 105(431), 881-896.Google Scholar
  41. Mayhew, B., J.M. McPherson, T. Rotolo, and L. Smith-Lovin (1995), “Sex and Race Homogeneity in Naturally Occuring Groups,” Social Forces, 74(1), 15-51.Google Scholar
  42. Meyer, J. and B. Rowan, (1977), “Institutional Organizations: Formal Structure as Myth and Ceremony,” American Journal of Sociology, 83(2), 340-363.Google Scholar
  43. Morgan, D.L., M.B. Neal, and P. Carder (1997), “The Stability of Core and Peripheral Networks over Time,” Social Networks, 19, 9-25.Google Scholar
  44. Orléan, A. (1989), “Mimetic Contagion and Speculative Bubbles,” Theory and Decision, 27, 63-92.Google Scholar
  45. Nowak, A., J. Szamrej, and B. Latané (1990), “From Private Attitude to Public Opinion: A Dynamic Theory of Social Impact,” Psychological Review, 97(3), 362-376.Google Scholar
  46. Rice, R. and C. Aydin (1991), “Attitudes toward New Organizational Technology: Network Proximity as a Mechanism for Social Information Processing,” Administrative Science Quarterly, 2, 219-244.Google Scholar
  47. Salancik, G. and J. Pfeffer (1978), “A Social Information Processing Approach to Job Attitudes and Task Design,” Administrative Science Quarterly, 23, 224-253.Google Scholar
  48. Schelling, T.C. (1969), “Models of Segregation,” American Economic Review, 59(2), 483-493.Google Scholar
  49. Scott, J. (1991), Social Network Analysis: A Handbook. Sage Publications, London.Google Scholar
  50. Sherif, M. (1936), The Psychology of Social Norms. Harper, New York.Google Scholar
  51. Shiller, R.J. (1995), “Conversation, Information, and Herd Behavior,” American Economic Review, 85(2), 181-185.Google Scholar
  52. Strogatz, S.H. (1994), Nonlinear Dynamics and Chaos. Addison-Wesley, New York.Google Scholar
  53. Suitor, J. and S. Keeton (1997), “Once a Friend, Always a Friend? Effects of Homophily on Women's Support Networks Across a Decade,” Social Networks, 19, 51-62.Google Scholar
  54. Victor, J.S. (1993), Satanic Panic: The Creation of a Contemporary Legend. Open Court.Google Scholar
  55. Victor, J.S. (1995), “The Dangers of Moral Panics,” Skeptic, 3(3), 44-51.Google Scholar
  56. Wasserman, S. and K. Faust, (1994), Social Network Analysis: Methods and Applications. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
  57. Wellman, B., R.Y. Wong, D. Tindal, and N. Nazer (1997) “A Decade of Network Change: Turnover, Persistence and Stability in Personal Communities,” Social Networks, 19, 27-50.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Kluwer Academic Publishers 1998

Authors and Affiliations

  • Carter Butts
    • 1
  1. 1.Department of Social and Decision SciencesCarnegie Mellon UniversityPittsburgh

Personalised recommendations