De Economist

, Volume 146, Issue 1, pp 23–58 | Cite as

Transaction Cost Economics: How It Works; Where It is Headed

  • Oliver E. Williamson
Article

Abstract

This paper begins with a sketch of the New Institutional Economics, with special emphasis on the ‘institutional environment’ (North and others) and the ‘institutions of governance’ (Coase and others). Thereafter the paper mainly emphasizes the applications of transaction cost economics to the study of governance, the object being to effect an economizing alignment between transactions, which differ in their attributes, and governance structures (firms, markets, hybrids, bureaus), which differ in their cost and competence. I raise a series of issues – phenomena of interest, describing human agents, describing firms, purposes served, scaling up – to which any would-be theory of the firm should be expected to speak and indicate how transaction cost economics responds to each. I thereafter describe the mechanisms through which transaction cost economics is implemented and develop some of the core conceptual supports out of which it works. Applications to public bureaus, strategic management, and intractable transactions are sketched.

firms governance econimizing mechanisms institutional economics 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

REFERENCES

  1. Alchian, Armen, and Harold Demsetz, 1972, ‘Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization,’ American Economic Review, 62, pp. 77–795.Google Scholar
  2. Aoki, Masahiko, 1990, ‘Toward an Economic Model of the Japanese Firm,’ Journal of Economic Literature, 28, pp. 1–27.Google Scholar
  3. Arrow, Kenneth J. 1963, ‘Uncertainty and the Welfare Economics of Medical Care,’ American Economic Review, 53, pp. 941–973.Google Scholar
  4. Arrow, Kenneth J., 1969, ‘The Organization of Economic Activity: Issues Pertinent to the Choice of Market Versus Nonmarket Allocation,’ in: The Analysis and Evaluation of Public Expenditure: The PPB System. 1, U.S. Joint Economic Committee, 91st Cong., 1st Sess. Washington, DC, US Government: Printing Office, pp. 59–73.Google Scholar
  5. Arrow, Kenneth J., 1987, ‘Reflections on the Essays,’ in: George Feiwel (ed.), Arrow and the Foundations of the Theory of Economic Policy, New York, New York University Press, pp. 727–734.Google Scholar
  6. Arrow, Kenneth J., 1989, ‘Competing Technologies, Increasing Returns, and Lock-in by Historical Events,’ Economic Journal, 99, pp. 116–131.Google Scholar
  7. Bain, Joe, 1968, Industrial Organization, New York, Wiley.Google Scholar
  8. Baker, George, Robert Gibbons, and Kevin Murphy, 1997, ‘Implicit Contracts and the Theory of the Firm,’ unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
  9. Barnard, Chester, 1938, The Functions of the Executive, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  10. Barnett, W., and G. Carroll, 1993, ‘How Institutional Constraints Affected the Organization of the Early American Telephone Industry,’ Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 9, pp. 98–126.Google Scholar
  11. Ben-Ner, Avner, and Theresa Van Hoomissen, 1991, ‘Nonprofit Organizations in the Mixed Economy,’ Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, 62, pp. 519–550.Google Scholar
  12. Bromley, Daniel, 1989, Economic Interest and Institutions, New York, Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
  13. Buchanan, James, 1975, ‘A Contractarian Paradigm for Applying Economic Theory,’ American Economic Review, 65, pp. 225–230.Google Scholar
  14. Chandler, Alfred D., Jr. 1962, Strategy and Structure, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press.Google Scholar
  15. Coase, Ronald H., 1937, ‘The Nature of the Firm,’ Economica N.S., 4, pp. 386–405. Reprinted in G.J. Stigler and K.E. Boulding (eds.), Readings in Price Theory, Homewood, IL, Richard D. Irwin.Google Scholar
  16. Coase, Ronald H., 1959, ‘The Federal Communications Commission,’ Journal of Law and Economics, 2, pp. 1–40.Google Scholar
  17. Coase, Ronald H., 1960, ‘The Problem of Social Cost,’ Journal of Law and Economics, 3, pp. 1–44.Google Scholar
  18. Coase, Ronald H., 1964, ‘The Regulated Industries: Discussion,’ American Economic Review, 54, pp. 194–197.Google Scholar
  19. Coase, Ronald H., 1972, ‘Industrial Organization: A Proposal for Research,’ in: V.R. Fuchs (ed.), Policy Issues and Reseach Opportunities in Industrial Organization, New York, National Bureau of Economic Research, pp. 59–73.Google Scholar
  20. Coase, Ronald H., 1978, ‘Economics and Contiguous Disciplines,’ Journal of Legal Studies, 7, pp. 201–211.Google Scholar
  21. Coase, Ronald H., 1984, ‘The New Institutional Economics,’ Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 140, pp. 229–231.Google Scholar
  22. Coase, Ronald H., 1992, ‘The Institutional Structure of Production,’ American Economic Review, 82, pp. 713–719.Google Scholar
  23. Commons, John, R., 1932, ‘The Problem of Correlating Law, Economics and Ethics,’ Wisconsin Law Review, 8, pp. 3–26.Google Scholar
  24. Cosmides, Leda, and John Tooby, 1996, ‘Are Humans Good Intuitive Statisticians After All?,’ Cognition, 58, pp. 1–73.Google Scholar
  25. Crocker, Keith, and Scott Masten, 1996, ‘Regulation and Administered Contracts Revisited: Lessons from Transaction Cost Economics for Public Utility Regulation,’ Journal of Regulatory Economics, 8, pp. 5–39.Google Scholar
  26. Cyert, Richard, and James March, 1963, A Behavioral Theory of the Firm, Englewood Cliffs, NJ, Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
  27. David, Paul, 1985, ‘Clio in the Economics of QWERTY,’ American Economic Review, 75, pp. 332–337.Google Scholar
  28. Davis, Lance, and Douglass North, 1971, Institutional Change and American Economic Growth, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  29. Debreu, Gerard, 1959, Theory of Value, New York, John Wiley and Sons.Google Scholar
  30. Demsetz, Harold, 1967, ‘Toward a Theory of Property Rights,’ American Economic Review, 57, pp. 347–359.Google Scholar
  31. Demsetz, Harold, 1969, ‘Information and Efficiency: Another Viewpoint,’ Journal of Law and Economics, 12, pp. 1–22.Google Scholar
  32. Dixit, Avinash, 1996, The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction Cost Politics Perspective, Cambridge, MIT Press.Google Scholar
  33. Dosi, Giovanni, 1988, ‘Sources, Procedures, and Microeconomic Effects of Innovation,’ Journal of Economic Literature, 26, pp. 1120–1171.Google Scholar
  34. Elster, Jon, 1994, ‘Arguing and Bargaining in Two Constituent Assemblies,’ unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
  35. Farnsworth, E. Allan, 1990, Farnsworth on Contracts, 1, Boston, Little-Brown.Google Scholar
  36. Fischer, Stanley, 1977, ‘Long-term Contracting, Sticky Prices, and Monetary Policy: Comment,’ Journal of Monetary Economics, 3, pp. 317–324.Google Scholar
  37. Fogel, Robert William, and Stanley L. Engerman (eds.), 1971, The Reinterpretation of American Economic History, New York, Harper and Row.Google Scholar
  38. Fogel, Robert William, and Stanley L. Engerman, 1974, Time on the Cross: The Economics of American Negro Slavery, Boston, Little-Brown.Google Scholar
  39. Fogel, Robert William, and Stanley L. Engerman, 1992, Without Consent or Contract: The Rise and Fall of American Slavery, New York, Norton.Google Scholar
  40. Furubotn, Eirik, and Rudolf Richter, 1991, ‘The New Institutional Economics: An Assessment,’ in: E. Furubotn en R. Richter (eds.), The New Institutional Economics, College Station, TX, Texas A&M University Press, pp. 1–32.Google Scholar
  41. Galanter, Marc, 1981, ‘Justice in Many Rooms: Courts, Private Ordering, and Indigenous Law,’ Journal of Legal Pluralism, 19, pp. 1–47.Google Scholar
  42. Georgescu-Roegen, N., 1971, The Entropy Law and Economic Process, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  43. Goldberg, Victor, 1976, ‘Regulation and Administered Contracts,’ Bell Journal of Economics, 7, pp. 426–452.Google Scholar
  44. Granovetter, Mark, 1985, ‘Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness,’ American Journal of Sociology, 91, pp. 481–501.Google Scholar
  45. Grossman, Sanford, and Oliver Hart, 1986, ‘The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Leteral Integration,’ Journal of Political Economy, 94, pp. 691–719.Google Scholar
  46. Hannan, Michael T., and John Freeman, 1977, ‘The Population Ecology of Organizations,’ American Journal of Sociology, 82, pp. 929–964.Google Scholar
  47. Hansmann, Henry, 1980, ‘The Role of Nonprofit Enterprise,’ Yale Law Journal, 89, pp. 835–901.Google Scholar
  48. Hart, Oliver, 1995, Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structure, New York, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  49. Hayek, Friedrich, 1945, ‘The Use of Knowledge in Society,’ American Economic Review, 35, pp. 519–530.Google Scholar
  50. Henisz, Witold, 1996, ‘A Case Study of the Institutions and Governance of Economic Reform: New Zealand's State Owned Enterprises,’ unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
  51. Hennipman, Pieter, 1995, Welfare Economics and the Theory of Economic Policy, Brookfield, VT, Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  52. Holmstrom, Bengt, 1979, ‘Moral Hazard and Observability,’ Bell Journal of Economics, 10, pp. 74–91.Google Scholar
  53. Holmstrom, Bengt, 1996, ‘The Firm as a Subeconomy,’ (unpublished manuscript).Google Scholar
  54. Holmstrom, Bengt, and Paul Milgrom, 1991, ‘Multi-task Principal-Agent Analysis,’ Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 7, pp. 24–52.Google Scholar
  55. Huntington, Samuel. P., 1996, The Clash of Civilizations and the Remaking of World Order, New York, Simon and Schuster.Google Scholar
  56. Hurst, J.W., 1964, Law and Economic Growth: The Legal History of the Lumber Industry in Wisconsin, 1836–1915, Madison, University of Wisconsin Press.Google Scholar
  57. James, Estelle, 1987, ‘The Nonprofit Sector in Comparative Perspective,’ in: Walter Powell (ed.), The Nonprofit Sector, New Haven, Yale University Press, pp. 397–415.Google Scholar
  58. Joskow, Paul, 1991, ‘The Role of Transaction Cost Economics in Antitrust and Public Utility Regulatory Policies,’ Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 7, pp. 53–83.Google Scholar
  59. Klein, Benjamin, R.A. Crawford, and A.A. Alchian, 1978, ‘Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process,’ Journal of Law and Economics, 21, pp. 297–326.Google Scholar
  60. Kreps, David, 1990, ‘Corporate Culture and Economic Theory, in: James Alt and Kenneth Shepsle (eds.), Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, pp. 90–143Google Scholar
  61. Kreps, David, 1996, ‘Markets and Hierarchies and (Mathematical) Economic Theory,’ Industrial and Corporate Change, 5, pp. 561–596.Google Scholar
  62. Kuhn, Thomas S., 1970, The Structure of Scientific Revolutions, 2nd ed., Chicago, University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  63. Levy, Brian, and Pablo Spiller, 1994, ‘The Institutional Foundations of Regulatory Commitment,’ Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 10, pp. 201–246.Google Scholar
  64. Lewis, Tracy, 1983, ‘Preemption, Divestiture, and Forward Contracting in a Market Dominated by a Single Firm,’ American Economic Review, 73, pp. 1092–1101.Google Scholar
  65. Llewellyn, Karl N., 1931, ‘What Price Contract? An Essay in Perspective,’ Yale Law Journal, 40, pp. 704–751.Google Scholar
  66. Lyons, Bruce, 1996, ‘Empirical Relevance of Efficient Contract Theory: Inter-firm Contracts,’ Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 12, pp. 27–52.Google Scholar
  67. Macneil, Ian R., 1974, ‘The Many Futures of Contracts,’ Southern California Law Review, 47, pp. 691–816.Google Scholar
  68. Macneil, Ian R., 1978, ‘Contracts, Adjustments of Long-term Economic Relations Under Classical, Neo-classical, and Relational Contract Law,’ Northwestern University Law Review, 72, pp. 854–906.Google Scholar
  69. Mahoney, Joseph, and Rajendran Pandian, 1992, ‘The Resource-based View within the Conversation of Strategic Management,’ Strategic Management Journal, 13, pp. 363–380.Google Scholar
  70. March, James G., and Herbert A. Simon, 1958, Organizations, New York, John Wiley and Sons.Google Scholar
  71. Maskin, Eric, and Jean Tirole, 1997, ‘Unforeseen Contingencies, Property Rights, and Incomplete Contracts,’ Unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
  72. Masten, Scott, 1995, ‘Introduction to Vol. II,’ in: Oliver Williamson and Scott Masten (eds.), Transaction Cost Economics, Brookfield, VT, Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  73. Matthews, R.C.O., 1986, ‘The Economics of Institutions and the Sources of Economic Growth,’ Economic Journal, 96, pp. 903–918.Google Scholar
  74. Michels, Robert, 1966, Political Parties, Glencoe, IL, Free Press.Google Scholar
  75. Moe, Terry, 1984, ‘The New Economics of Organization,’ American Journal of Political Science, 28, pp. 739–777.Google Scholar
  76. Moe, Terry, 1990, ‘The Politics of Structural Choice: Toward a Theory of Public Bureaucracy,’ in: Oliver Williamson (ed.), Organization Theory, New York, Oxford University Press, pp. 116–153.Google Scholar
  77. Nee, Victor, 1997, ‘Embeddedness and Beyond,’ in: Mary Brinton and Victor Nee (eds.), The New Institutionalism in Sociology, New York, Russell Sage.Google Scholar
  78. Nelson, Richard, and Sidney Winter, 1982, An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  79. Nickerson, Jackson A., 1997, ‘Toward and Economizing Theory of Strategy: The Choice of Strategic Position, Assets, and Organizational Form,’ University of California, Berkeley, unpublished Ph.D. dissertation.Google Scholar
  80. North, Douglass, 1981, Structure and Change in Economic History, New York, Norton.Google Scholar
  81. North, Douglass, 1984, ‘Transaction Costs, Institutions, and Economic History,’ Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 140, pp. 7–17.Google Scholar
  82. North, Douglass, 1990, ‘A Transaction Cost Theory of Politics,’ Journal of Theoretical Politics, 2, pp. 355–367.Google Scholar
  83. North, Douglass, 1991, ‘Institutions,’ Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5, pp. 97–112.Google Scholar
  84. North, Douglass, 1994, ‘Economic Performance Through Time,’ American Economic Review, 84, pp. 357–368.Google Scholar
  85. North, Douglass, and Barry Weingast, 1989, ‘Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in 17th Century England,’ Journal of Economic History, 49, pp. 803–832.Google Scholar
  86. Olson, Mancur, 1996, ‘Big Bills Left on the Sidewalk: Why Some Nations Are Rich, and Others Are Poor,’ Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10, pp. 3–24.Google Scholar
  87. Priest, George, 1993, ‘The Origins of Utility Regulation and the “Theories of Regulation” Debate,’ Journal of Law and Economics, 36, pp. 289–323.Google Scholar
  88. Putnam, Robert. D., Robert Leonardi, and Rafaella Y. Nanetti, 1993, Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy, Princeton, NJ, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  89. Robinson, James, 1996, ‘Physician-Hospital Integration and the Economic Theory of the Firm,’ unpublished manuscript, School of Public Health, University of California, Berkeley.Google Scholar
  90. Rose-Ackerman, Susan, 1996, ‘Altruism, Nonprofits, and Economic Theory,’ Journal of Economic Literature, 34, pp. 701–728.Google Scholar
  91. Rosenberg, Nathan, and L.E. Birdzell, 1986, How the West Grew Rich: The Transformation of the Industrial World, New York, Basic Books.Google Scholar
  92. Rubin, Edward, 1996, ‘The Phenomenology of Contract,’ Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 152, pp. 123–139.Google Scholar
  93. Samuels, Warren J., (ed.), 1988, Institutional Economics (3 vols.), Aldershot, Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  94. Schlegel, John Henry, 1979, ‘American Legal Realism and Empirical Science: From The Yale Experience,’ Buffalo Law Review, 29, pp. 195–323.Google Scholar
  95. Schultz, George, 1995, ‘Economics in Action,’ American Economic Review, 85, pp. 1–8.Google Scholar
  96. Scott, Kenneth, 1996, ‘The Evolving Roles of Contract Law,’ Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 152, pp. 55–58.Google Scholar
  97. Shelanski, Howard, and Peter Klein, 1995, ‘Empirical Research in Transaction Cost Economics: A Review and Assessment,’ Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 11, pp. 335–361.Google Scholar
  98. Simon, Herbert, 1985, ‘Human Nature in Politics: The Dialogue of Psychology with Political Science,’ American Political Science Review, 79, pp. 293–304.Google Scholar
  99. Simon, Herbert, 1991, ‘Organizations and Markets,’ Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5, pp. 25–44.Google Scholar
  100. Smith, Vernon, 1994, ‘Economics in the Laboratory', Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8, pp. 113–131.Google Scholar
  101. Stigler, George J., 1983, Comments in: Edmund W. Kitch (ed.), ‘The Fire of Truth: A Remembrance of Law and Economics at Chicago.Google Scholar
  102. Stigler, George J., 1988, ‘Palgrave's Dictionary of Economics,’ Journal of Economic Literature, 26, pp. 1729–1736.Google Scholar
  103. Stigler, George J., 1992, ‘Law or Economics?,’ Journal of Law and Economics, 35, pp. 455–468.Google Scholar
  104. Summers, Clyde, 1969, ‘Collective Agreements and the Law of Contracts,’ Yale Law Journal, 78, pp. 537–575.Google Scholar
  105. Teece, David J., Gary Pisano, and Amy Shuen, 1996, ‘Dynamic Capabilities and Strategic Management,’ Strategic Management Journal, 17, pp. xx–yy.Google Scholar
  106. Teece, David J., Gary Pisano, and Amy Shuen, Richard Rumelt, Giovanni Dosi, and Sidney Winter, 1993, ‘Understanding Corporate Coherence,’ Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 22, pp. 1–30.Google Scholar
  107. Thompson, James D., 1967, Organizations in Action, New York, McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
  108. Tullock, Gordon, 1996, ‘Legal Heresy: President's Address to the Western Economic Association,’ Economic Inquiry, 34, pp. 1–9.Google Scholar
  109. Williamson, Oliver, 1971, ‘The Vertical Integration of Production: Market Failure Considerations,’ American Economic Review, 61, pp. 112–123.Google Scholar
  110. Williamson, Oliver, 1975, Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications, New York, Free Press.Google Scholar
  111. Williamson, Oliver, 1976, ‘Franchise Bidding for Natural Monopolies - In General and with Respect to CATV,’ Bell Journal of Economics, 7, pp. 73–104.Google Scholar
  112. Williamson, Oliver, 1979, ‘Transaction Cost Economics: The Governance of Contractual Relations,’ Journal of Law and Economics, 22, pp. 233–261.Google Scholar
  113. Williamson, Oliver, 1985, The Economics Institutions of Capitalism, New York, Free Press.Google Scholar
  114. Williamson, Oliver, 1991a, ‘Comparative Economic Organization: The Analysis of Discrete Structural Alternatives,’ Administrative Science Quarterly, 36, pp. 269–296.Google Scholar
  115. Williamson, Oliver, 1991b, ‘Strategizing, Economizing, and Economic Organization,’ Strategic Management Journal, 12, pp. 75–94.Google Scholar
  116. Williamson, Oliver, 1993a, ‘Calculativeness, Trust, and Economic Organization,’ Journal of Law and Economics, 36, pp. 453–486.Google Scholar
  117. Williamson, Oliver, 1993b, ‘Transaction Cost Economics Meets Posnerian Law and Economics,’ Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 149, pp. 99–118.Google Scholar
  118. Williamson, Oliver, 1996a, The Mechanisms of Governance, New York, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  119. Williamson, Oliver, 1996b, ‘Revisiting Legal Realism: The Law, Economics, and Organization Perspective,’ Industrial and Corporate Change, 5, pp. 383–420.Google Scholar
  120. Williamson, Oliver, 1997, ‘Public and Private Bureaus,’ unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
  121. Williamson, Oliver, and Scott Masten (eds.), 1995, Transaction Cost Economics, Brookfield, VT, Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  122. Wilson, James Q, 1989, Bureaucracy, New York, Basic Books.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Kluwer Academic Publishers 1998

Authors and Affiliations

  • Oliver E. Williamson
    • 1
  1. 1.University of CaliforniaBerkeley.

Personalised recommendations