Skip to main content
Log in

The Reform of the Transparency Directive: Minimum or Full Harmonisation of Ownership Disclosure?

  • Articles
  • Published:
European Business Organization Law Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The reform of the Transparency Directive is presently on the political agenda, with one of the key questions focusing on the level of harmonisation: should the current minimum harmonisation be retained or is a move towards full harmonisation advisable? After confirming legal competence for the full harmonisation of European capital markets law, this article weighs the pros and cons of full harmonisation in the case of ownership disclosure rules. The ability to overcome the costly legal fragmentation of the current regulatory regime for notification of major shareholdings throughout Europe is revealed as the greatest benefit of full harmonisation. As full harmonisation not only reduces compliance costs but also boosts investor confidence, all market participants stand to benefit. Despite this, full harmonisation also carries certain costs as it inhibits regulatory competition, increases complexity in implementing EU law in national legal systems and carries the danger of a petrification effect. The article reveals that these cost factors are not sufficient to undermine the case for full harmonisation for financial instruments requiring notification, as well as for thresholds, timeframes and notification formats. It goes on to show that legal regimes can retain their adaptive efficiency by allowing them to conduct temporary legislative experiments. However, the article refrains from generalising this finding, encouraging a targeted full harmonisation approach for the Transparency Directive.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  1. See, for example, S. Weatherill, ‘Maximum or Minimum Harmonisation: What Kind of “Europe” Do We Want?’, in K. Boele-Woelki and F.W. Grodheide, eds., The Future of European Contract Law, Liber Amicorum E.H. Hondius (Alphen aan den Rijn, Kluwer Law International 2007) p. 133; T. Wilhelmsson, ‘Introduction: Harmonization and National Cultures’, in T. Wilhelmsson, E. Paunio and A. Pohjolainen, eds., Private Law and the Many Cultures of Europe (Alphen aan den Rijn, Kluwer Law International 2007) p. 3; recently, L. Niglia, ‘Of Harmonization and Fragmentation: The Problem of Legal Transplants in the Europeanization of Private Law’, 17 Maastricht Journal of European and Comparative Law (2010) p. 116; see also the comprehensive volume edited by B. Gsell and C. Herresthal, eds., Vollharmonisierung im Privatrecht (Tübingen, Mohr Siebeck 2009)

    Google Scholar 

  2. See, for example, G. Howells and R. Schulze, eds., Modernising and Harmonising Consumer Contract Law (Munich, Sellier, European Law Publishers 2009); B. Gsell and H.M. Schellhase, ‘Vollharmonisiertes Verbraucherkreditrecht — Ein Vorbild für die weitere europäische Angleichung des Verbrauchervertragsrechts?’, 64 JuristenZeitung (JZ) (2009) p. 20.

    Google Scholar 

  3. Directive 2004/109/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 15 December 2004 on the harmonisation of transparency requirements in relation to information about issuers whose securities are admitted to trading on a regulated market and amending Directive 2001/34/EG, OJ L 390 of 31.12.2004, p. 38.

  4. See European Commission, Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council on consumer rights of 8 October 2008, COM(2008) 614 final; now more cautiously, European Commission, Green Paper on policy options for progress towards a European Contract Law for consumers and businesses, 1 July 2010, COM(2010) 348 final, at p. 6; see M. Stürner, ‘Editorial’, Zeitschrift für Gemeinschaftsprivatrecht (GPR) (2010) p. 157.

  5. There is full harmonisation when the application of a directive requires a regulatory result that cannot be made stronger or weaker by the Member States’ implementation; in greater detail, W.-H. Roth, in Gsell and Herresthal, eds., supra n. 1, p. 13, at p. 18 et seq. In the view of some authors, however, the term maximum harmonisation describes cross-border processes and forbids the host state to enact stricter national regulations; see T.M.J. Möllers, in Gsell and Herresthal, supra n. 1, p. 247, at p. 250; J. Herbst, ‘Revision of the Investment Services Directive’, 11 Journal of Financial Regulation and Compliance (2003) p. 211, at p. 213; M. Tison, ‘Financial Market Integration in the Post FSAP Era. In Search of Overall Conceptual Consistency in the Regulatory Framework’, in G. Ferrarini and E. Wymeersch, eds., Investor Protection in Europe (Oxford, Oxford University Press 2006) p. 443, at p. 446 and n. 6. It seems though that both terms are quite often used interchangeably, see, for example, T. Ackermann, ‘Buying Legitimacy? The Commission’s Proposal on Consumer Rights’, 21 European Business Law Review (2010) p. 587; V. Mak, ‘The Degree of Harmonisation in the Proposed Consumer Rights Directive: A Review in Light of Liability for Products’, in Howells and Schulze, eds., supra n. 2, p. 305; A. Johnston and H. Unberath, ‘European Private Law by Directives: Approach and Challenges’, in C. Twigg-Flesner, ed., The Cambridge Companion of European Union Private Law (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press 2010) p. 85, at p. 88 et seq.

  6. See V. Emmerich and R. Doehner, ‘Maximalharmonisiertes Verbraucherkreditrecht und Binnenmarktkompetenz’, in W.-R. Bub, R. Knieper, R. Metz and G. Winter, eds., Zivilrecht im Sozialstaat — Festschriftfür Peter Derleder (Baden-Baden, Nomos 2005) p. 367; T. Riehm and B. Schreindorfer, ‘Das Harmonisierungskonzept der neuen Verbraucherkreditrichtlinie’, GPR (2008) p. 244; M. Tamm, ‘Das Grünbuch der Kommission zum Verbraucheracquis und das Modell der Vollharmonisierung’, Europäische Zeitschrift für Wirtschaftsrecht (2007) p. 756; T. Wilhelmsson, ‘Full Harmonisation of Consumer Contract Law?’, Zeitschrift für Europäisches Privatrecht (ZEuP) (2008) p. 225; also sceptical, Gsell and Schellhase, supra n. 2; recently and in depth, H.C. Grigoleit, ‘Der Verbraucheracquis und die Entwicklung des Europäischen Privatrechts’, 210 Archiv für die civilistische Praxis (2010) p. 354; for a neutral presentation of pros and cons, M. Stürner, ‘Das Konzept der Vollharmonisierung — eine Einführung’, in M. Stürner, ed., Vollharmonisierung im Europäischen Verbraucherrecht? (Munich, Sellier, European Law Publishers 2010) p. 3.

    Google Scholar 

  7. See B. Zypries, ‘Der Vorschlag für eine Richtlinie über Verbraucherrechte’, ZEuP (2009) p. 225.

  8. See H. Fleischer and K.U. Schmolke, ‘Das Anschleichen an eine börsennotierte Aktiengesellschaft — Überlegungen zur Beteiligungstransparenz de lege lata und de lege ferenda’, Neue Zeitschrift für Gesellschaftsrecht (NZG) (2009), at p. 408 et seq.; also likely leaning in this direction, U. Brandt, ‘Meldepflichten für aktienbasierte Instrumente: Anmerkungen zum Diskussionsentwurf des Bundesfinanzministeriums (AnlegerStärkungsG)’, Zeitschrift für Bank- und Kapitalmarktrecht (2010) p. 270, at p. 275; recognising the cost benefit of full harmonisation, D.A. Zetzsche, ‘Against Mandatory Disclosure of Economic-only Positions Referenced to Shares of European Issuers — Twenty Arguments against the CESR Proposal’, 11 European Business Organization Law Review (2010) p. 231, at p. 250; undecided, M.C. Schouten, ‘The Case for Mandatory Ownership Disclosure’, 15 Stanford Journal of Law, Business & Finance (2009) p. 127, at pp. 181–182; but see also N. Moloney, ‘EU Financial Market Regulation after the Global Financial Crisis: “More Europe” or More Risks?’, 47 Common Market Law Review (CMLR) (2010) p. 1317, at p. 1372 et seq., pointing to certain ‘centralisation risks’; assuming that full harmonisation has already taken place as far as capital markets law enacted according to the Lamfalussy Process is concerned, T.M.J. Möllers, ‘Europäische Methoden- und Gesetzgebungslehre im Kapitalmarktrecht: Vollharmonisierung, Generalklauseln und soft law im Rahmen des Lamfalussy-Verfahrens als Mittel zur Etablierung von Standards’, ZEuP (2008) p. 480, at p. 499 et seq., who does not include the Transparency Directive.

  9. See European Commission, Consultation document on the modernisation of the Directive 2004/109/EC on the harmonisation of transparency requirements in relation to information about issuers whose securities are admitted to trading on a regulated market, 27 May 2010, Questions 19 and 20: ‘Would it be desirable to set up a uniform regime … for the notification of major shareholdings of voting rights? … If a fully uniform EU regime is not possible because of insurmountable legal barriers, should Member States be prevented from adopting more stringent requirements than those of the Transparency Directive regarding the notification of major holdings of voting rights?’

  10. Council Directive 88/627/EEC of 12 December 1988 on the information to be published when a major holding in a listed company is acquired or disposed of, OJ L 348 of 17.12.1988, p. 62.

  11. BGBl. I 1994, 1749.

  12. Explanatory Notes on the Government Bill for the Second Financial Market Development Act, BT-Drs. 12/6679, p. 52.

  13. Directive 2004/109/EC, supra n. 3; details on its background and development in N. Moloney, EC Securities Regulation, 2nd edn. (Oxford, Oxford University Press 2008), at p. 170 et seq.

  14. See the first recital, together with the second, of the Transparency Directive II, supra n. 3.

  15. See Moloney, supra n. 14, at p. 185 et seq.

  16. BGBl. I 2007, 10.

  17. Reason stated explicitly in the Explanatory Notes on the Government Bill for the Transparency Directive Implementation Act, BT-Drs. 16/2498, pp. 26, 28 and 34.

  18. Ibid., p. 28.

  19. Ibid.

  20. BGBl. I 2008, 1666.

  21. See the Explanatory Notes on the Government Bill for the Risk Limitation Act, BT-Drs. 16/7438, at p. 14.

  22. In detail, H. Fleischer, ‘Mitteilungspflichten für Inhaber wesentlicher Beteiligungen (§ 27a WpHG)’, Die Aktiengesellschaft (AG) (2008) p. 873, with additional references.

  23. See the Explanatory Notes, supra n. 22.

  24. In greater detail, D. Dehlinger and M. Zimmermann, in A. Fuchs, ed., WpHG (Munich, C.H. Beck 2009) para. 22, marg. no. 82 et seq.; critical of the fact that the WpÜG and WpHG both have similar provisions for calculating voting rights, H. Fleischer, ‘Finanzinvestoren im ordnungs-politischen Gesamtgefüge von Aktien-, Bankaufsichts- und Kapitalmarktrecht’, 37 Zeitschrift für Unternehmens- und Gesellschaftsrecht (ZGR) (2008) p. 185, at p. 196 et seq., with additional references

  25. See Federal Government, Anlegerschutz- und Funktionsverbesserungsgesetz, BR-Dr 584/10; on the subject of the German Federal Ministry of Finance’s Draft Proposal of 11 May 2010, see H. Fleischer and K.U. Schmolke, ‘Zum beabsichtigten Ausbau der kapitalmarktrechtlichen Beteiligungstransparenz bei modernen Finanzinstrumenten (§§ 25, 25a DiskE-WpHG)’, NZG (2010) p. 846; see also Brandt, supra n. 8; T. Brouwer, ‘Neue Transparenzvorgaben auf dem Weg zum Kapitalmarkt — Leerverkäufe und Beteiligungstransparenz stehen auf dem Prüfstand’, AG (2010) p. 404; A. Merkner and M. Sustmann, ‘Vorbei mit dem unbemerkten Anschleichen an börsennotierte Unternehmen?’, NZG (2010) p. 681; C. Teichmann and D. Epe, ‘Neuer Regelungsansatz in der kapitalmarktrechtlichen Beteiligungstransparenz: Generalklausel statt Fallgruppen-Lösung’, Zeitschrift für Wirtschafts- und Bankrecht (2010) p. 1477; U. Wackerbarth, ‘Ein Seismograph für Übernahmeaktivitäten’, Zeitschrift für Wirtschaftsrecht (2010) p. 1527.

  26. In detail, Fleischer, supra n. 23, with additional references.

  27. For more details, see the references supra n. 26.

  28. A quick overview is provided by Fleischer and Schmolke, supra n. 26, at p. 847 et seq., with additional references.

  29. See Federal Government, supra n. 26, at p. 23 et seq.

  30. See the Commission Staff Working Document, Report on more stringent measures concerning Directive 2004/109/EC, SEC(2008) 3033 final, 10 December 2008, Annex 5.

  31. These national provisions are of course based on the regulatory option provided in Art. 1(1) of the Transparency Directive I.

  32. For details, see the Commission Staff Working Document, supra n. 31.

  33. See W. Dwyer, ‘Final Rules on Information about Major Shareholdings’, Journal of International Banking Law and Regulation (2009) p. 435.

  34. See P.-H. Conac, ‘Le nouveau régime des franchissements de seuils issu de l’ordonnance n° 2009-105 du 30 janvier 2009 et du Règlement général de l’AMF’, Revue des sociétés (2009) p. 477.

  35. For a brief overview of the EU legislator’s reform-related considerations, see Fleischer and Schmolke, supra n. 26, at p. 847, with additional references.

  36. See Commission Staff Working Document, The review of the operation of Directive 2004/109/EC: emerging issues, SEC(2009) 611, 27 May 2010, para. 25, with n. 74 and Annex 7.

  37. For more detail, see Mazars, Transparency Directive Assessment Report (2010) 3.3.7 (p. 106 et seq.), 3.6.1.4 (p. 123 et seq.) and 3.8 (p. 144 et seq.).

  38. Moloney, supra n. 14, at p. 195; but see also M.C. Schouten and M.M. Siems, ‘The Evolution of Ownership Disclosure Rules across Countries’, 10 Journal of Corporate Law Studies (JCLS) (2010) p. 451, who, in the context of a worldwide comparison of the rules on shareholding transparency, report a growing convergence (through increasingly stringent regulation) among the notification regimes of the 25 countries examined.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  39. On the company law concept of the harmonisation of core areas, deregulation and the careful development of supranational corporate forms, see European Commission, Communication from the Commission of 10.7.2007, COM(2007) 394 final; see also T. Baums, ‘Aktuelle Entwicklungen im Europäischen Gesellschaftsrecht’, AG (2007) p. 57; H. Fleischer, ‘Supranationale Gesellschaftsformen in der Europäischen Union — Prolegomena zu einer Theorie supranationaler Verbandsformen’, 174 Zeitschrift für das gesamte Handels- und Wirtschaftsrecht (ZHR) (2010) p. 385, at p. 405; J. Schürnbrand, ‘Vollharmonisierung im Gesellschaftsrecht’, in Gsell and Herresthal, eds., supra n. 1, p. 273, at p. 278 et seq.

  40. See T.M.J. Möllers, ‘Zur “Unverzüglichkeit” einer Ad-hoc-Mitteilung im Kontext nationaler und europäischer Dogmatik’, in K.P. Berger, G. Borges, H. Herrmann, A. Schlüter and U. Wackerbarth, eds., Zivil- und Wirtschaftsrecht im Europäischen und Globalen Kontext, Festschrift für Norbert Horn zum 70. Geburtstag (Berlin, De Gruyter 2006) p. 473, at p. 485; Möllers, supra n. 8, at p. 499 et seq.; Möllers, supra n. 5, at pp. 250 et seq. and 256 et seq.; see also T. Buchmann, Umsetzung vollharmonisierender Richtlinien (Baden-Baden, Nomos 2008), at pp. 94 et seq. and 104; similarly, it seems, with regard to the Markets in Financial Instruments Directive, J. Thieme, Wertpapierdienstleistungen im Binnenmarkt (Baden-Baden, Nomos 2008), at p. 526 et seq.; distinguishing, Tison, supra n. 5, at p. 445 et seq. In general on the change in regulatory strategies in the EU’s financial markets law, Moloney, supra n. 14, at pp. 9 et seq. and 11 et seq.; and recently again, Moloney, supra n. 8, at p. 1335 et seq., with particular focus on the most recent regulation strategies following the financial crisis and on the upcoming change in the regulatory architecture.

    Google Scholar 

  41. See, e.g., European Commission, White Paper on Financial Services Policy 2005–2010, 1 December 2005, COM(2005) 629 final, at p. 7; summarising, Buchmann, supra n. 42, at p. 62 et seq.; K.U. Schmolke, ‘Der Lamfalussy-Prozess im Europäischen Kapitalmarktrecht — eine Zwischenbilanz’, NZG (2005) p. 912, at p. 915. A resolution by the European Parliament from April 2008 can be understood as going in the same direction; see European Parliament, Report of 2 April 2008: ‘[The European Parliament] asks the Commission, however, to review whether the transposition of directives such as the Transparency Directive has led to “gold-plating” by Member States…’.

  42. European Commission, Report to the Council, the European Parliament, the European Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions of 27 May 2010 on the operation of Directive 2004/109/EC on the harmonisation of transparency requirements in relation to information about issuers whose securities are admitted to trading on a regulated market, SEC (2010) 611, COM (2010) 243 final, para. 12 (p. 4). Clearer still, European Commission, supra n. 9, at p. 11: ‘More stringent and additional rules at national level as well as provisions in the Directive allowing for derogations/discretion at national level results in an insufficient harmonisation level… The consequence of the lack of harmonisation and of unclear rules is that compliance costs are higher for investors and issuers and that disclosed information may not always be comparable. As a result, markets are segmented and investor confidence may diminish.’

  43. See Mazars, supra n. 39, 3.1.7 (p. 97); adopting this proposal, Commission Staff Working Document, supra n. 38, para. 25.

  44. The ESME advises the Commission with regard to the application of capital market law directives. The group was established by Commission Decision 2006/288/EC of 30 March 2006, OJ L 106 of 19.04.2006, p. 14.

  45. See ESME, Views on the issue of transparency of holdings of cash settled derivatives, November 2009; it had already touched upon the issue of ‘acting in concert’ in ESME, Preliminary views on the definition of ‘acting in concert’ between the Transparency Directive and the Takeover Bids Directive, November 2008, at p. 3.

  46. See CESR, Consultation Paper: CESR proposal to extend major shareholding notifications to instruments of similar economic effect to holding shares and entitlements to acquire shares, CESR/09-1215b, January 2010.

  47. For a brief overview of the content of the Consultation Paper see Fleischer and Schmolke, supra n. 26, at p. 851. Despite the CESR’s silence on the matter, there was mostly agreement among the 33 statements filed before 31 March 2010 that a transparency regime, regardless of its nature, should be fully harmonised Europe-wide, as the current legal fragmentation is costly. A list of the statements filed is available at: <http://www.cesr.eu/index.php?page=responses&id=157>.

  48. See Fleischer and Schmolke, supra n. 8, at p. 409; recently also C. Clerc and F. Demarigny, ‘Faut-il réformer la Directive Transparence?’, Revue Trimestrielle de Droit Financier (2010) p. 20, at p. 26.

  49. For example, Zetzsche, supra n. 8, at p. 250; thus generally in favour of the full harmonisation of secondary legislation in capital markets law, Möllers, supra n. 8, at pp. 502 et seq. and 504.

  50. For example, Schouten, supra n. 8, at p. 181 et seq., who, at the same time, also points to possible advantages of regulatory competition in the field of shareholding transparency.

  51. See Deutsches Aktieninstitut, Response to the EU Commission’s Public Consultation, 23 August 2010, at p. 18.

  52. See Zetzsche, supra n. 8, at p. 250; generally also G. Bachmann, ‘Kapitalmarktrechtliche Probleme bei der Zusammenführung von Unternehmen’, 172 ZHR (2008) p. 597, at p. 633.

    Google Scholar 

  53. Doubts, for example, in Ackermann, supra n. 5, at p. 590 et seq.; Tamm, supra n. 6, at p. 759 et seq.; K. Tonner and M. Tamm, ‘Der Vorschlag einer Richtlinie über Rechte der Verbraucher und seine Auswirkungen auf das nationale Verbraucherrecht’, 64 JZ (2009) p. 277, at p. 284 et seq.; Emmerich and Doehner, supra n. 6, at p. 367 et seq. (on the Consumer Credit Directive); in detail also Grigoleit, supra n. 6, at p. 364 et seq.; in general on the EU competences for fully harmonising private law, see Roth, supra n. 5, at p. 13 et seq.

    Google Scholar 

  54. Directive 2008/48/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 23 April 2008 on credit agreements for consumers and repealing Council Directive 87/102/EEC, OJ L 133 of 22 May 2008, p. 66.

  55. For an overview of the Treaty provisions on competence being cited for the Financial Services Action Plan regulatory measures, see Moloney, supra n. 14, at p. 8.

  56. Suffice it to cite M. Möstl, ‘Grenzen der Rechtsangleichung im europäischen Binnenmarkt’, 37 Europarecht (EuR) (2002) p. 318, at p. 324.

    Google Scholar 

  57. Suffice it to cite Roth, supra n. 5, at pp. 13 and 22 et seq.

  58. ECJ, Judgment of 5 October 2000 in Case C-376/98 Germany v. European Parliament and Council [2000] ECR I-8419, at para. 83 et seq.

  59. Ibid., at para. 99.

  60. Summing up, Roth, supra n. 5, at pp. 13 and 30; see also Ackermann, supra n. 5, at p. 593 et seq.; N. Moloney, ‘Confidence and Competence: The Conundrum of EC Capital Markets Law’, 4 JCLS (2004) p. 1, at p. 46 et seq.

    Google Scholar 

  61. See ECJ, supra n. 60, at paras. 95 et seq. and 106 et seq.

  62. Suffice it to cite K.U. Schmolke, ‘Institutionelle Anleger und Corporate Governance — Traditionelle institutionelle Investoren vs. Hedgefonds’, ZGR (2007) p. 701, at pp. 717 et seq. and 724 et seq.

  63. On the German discussion, Fleischer and Schmolke, supra n. 8, at p. 403; Fleischer and Schmolke, supra n. 26, at p. 848.

  64. Generally on the suitability of full harmonisation as a means of combating significant distortions of competition, see Roth, supra n. 5, at p. 34; similarly on financial market regulation as a whole, Moloney, supra n. 14: ‘In principle, harmonization of rules is justified where it is necessary to correct a market failure which extends beyond national boundaries and which cannot be corrected by action by individual States, … and where doing so increases welfare, taking into account the costs of harmonization. … Typical market failures include protectionist barriers, the regulatory costs and inefficiencies represented by multiple regimes…’.

  65. As, for example, W. Kahl, in C. Callies and M. Ruffert, eds., EUV/EGV, 3rd edn. (Munich, C.H. Beck 2007), at Art. 95 EGV, marg. no. 13, with additional references; C. Tietje, in E. Grabitz and M. Hilf, eds., Das Recht der Europäischen Union, 21st loose-leaf suppl. (Munich, C.H. Beck 2003), at Art. 95 EGV, marg. no. 30. For a similar discussion in the context of Art. 50(2)(g) TFEU, see A. Randelzhofer and U. Forsthoff, in E. Grabitz and M. Hilf, eds., Das Recht der Europäischen Union, 18th loose-leaf suppl. (Munich, C.H. Beck 2001), at Art. 44 EGV, marg. no. 16.

  66. ECJ, Judgment of 24 November 1993 in Joined Cases C-267/91 and C-268/91 Keck and Mithouard [1993] ECR I-6097, at paras. 15–17.

  67. See Roth, supra n. 5, at p. 34 et seq.; Tison, supra n. 5, at p. 450 et seq., actually argues along these lines against ‘maximum harmonisation’ in the field of financial markets law.

  68. Similarly, J. Basedow, ‘A Common Contract Law for the Common Market’, 33 CMLR (1996) p. 1169, at p. 1183; O. Remien, in R. Schulze, M. Zuleeg and S. Kadelbach, eds., Europarecht, 2nd edn. (Baden-Baden, Nomos 2010), at para. 14, marg. nos. 7 et seq.; W.-H. Roth, ‘Rechtsetzungskompetenzen für das Privatrecht in der Europäischen Union’, Europäisches Wirtschafts- und Steuerrecht (2008) p. 401, at p. 408 et seq.; Roth, supra n. 5, at p. 38 et seq.; Grigoleit, supra n. 6, at p. 367 et seq.; Ackermann, supra n. 5, at p. 594 et seq.; unclear, J.M. Smits, The Making of European Private Law (Antwerp, Intersentia 2002), at pp. 14–15.

    Google Scholar 

  69. Convincingly, Roth, supra n. 5, at p. 38 et seq.; Roth, supra n. 70, at p. 412. On the transformation of the aims of Art. 50 TFEU after the transitional period from the abolition of restrictions on establishment to the facilitation of the freedom of establishment, see M. Kotzur, in R. Geiger, D.-E. Khan and M. Kotzur, eds., EUV/AEUV, 5th edn. (Munich, C.H. Beck 2010), at Art. 50 AEUV, marg. no. 1.

  70. Moloney, supra n. 14, at p. 27.

  71. With regard to the uniform distribution of goods and services throughout the single market, see Roth, supra n. 5, at p. 38 et seq.

  72. Sceptical in view of the particularities of local markets, Moloney, supra n. 14, at p. 8 et seq.; with regard to the legislative aim of fostering ‘investor competence’, see also Moloney, supra n. 62, at p. 46 et seq.

  73. Recently taking stock of the situation in respect of different fields of the law, N. Reich, ‘Von der Minimal- zur Voll- zur “Halbharmonisierung” — Ein europäisches Privatrechtsdrama in fünf Akten’, ZEuP (2010) p. 7, with additional references.

  74. European Commission, Consumer Policy Strategy 2002–2006, COM(2002) 208 final, at p. 14 et seq.; European Commission, Green Paper on the Review of the Consumer Acquis, COM(2006) 744 final, at p. 10.

  75. On the legal fragmentation in consumer protection law, see European Commission, supra n. 4, at p. 2, which bases its regulatory plan of full harmonisation on this finding; see also the results of the survey in S. Vogenauer and S. Weatherill, ‘The European Community’s Competence for a Comprehensive Harmonisation of Contract Law — An Empirical Analysis’, 30 European Law Review (2005) p. 821; S. Vogenauer and S. Weatherill, ‘Eine empirische Untersuchung zur Angleichung des Vertragsrechts in der EG’, 60 JZ (2005) p. 870, at p. 874 et seq.

  76. See European Commission, Communication from the Commission on Cross-Border Business to Consumer e-Commerce in the EU, 22 October 2009, COM(2009) 557 final; making reference thereto, European Commission (2006), supra n. 76, at p. 5 et seq. (sub 3.1.).

  77. Generally, in respect of goods and services, see N. Balta and J. Delgado, ‘Home Bias and Market Integration in the EU’, 55 CESifo Economic Studies (2009) p. 110 and additional references.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  78. European Commission, supra n. 4, at p. 2.

  79. See Möllers, supra n. 8, at p. 503; in contrast, G. Hertig, ‘Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services’, 14 International Review of Law and Economics (1994) p. 177, who deems ‘imperfect mutual recognition’ to be a ‘second best’ solution.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  80. See Möllers, supra n. 8, at p. 502; Tamm, supra n. 6, at p. 758; Wilhelmsson, supra n. 6, at p. 226; see also Moloney, supra n. 14, at p. 37 et seq., with p. 28 et seq.; see lastly Moloney, supra n. 8, at p. 1372 et seq., who also points to the ‘risk of systemic regulatory error’ related to centralised EU-wide regulation.

  81. See G. Wagner, ‘The Economics of Harmonization: The Case of Contract Law’, 39 CMLR (2002) p. 995, at p. 1012.

    Google Scholar 

  82. Critical with regard to the prevention of ‘legislative experimenting’ at the Member State level, J. Stuyck, E. Terryn and T. van Dyck, ‘Confidence through Fairness? The New Directive on Unfair Business-to-Consumer Commercial Practices in the Internal Market’, 43 CMLR (2006) p. 107, at p. 116; Moloney, supra n. 8, at p. 1373 et seq.

    Google Scholar 

  83. See also Moloney, supra n. 14, at p. 10: ‘The minimum harmonization model allowed a degree of regulatory competition … above the minimum level…’.

  84. Generally on all harmonisation measures regardless of their type, see Moloney, supra n. 14, at p. 28: ‘Inadequate harmonization which sits uneasily with national enforcement remedies and domestic rules is not only unlikely to deliver efficiencies but is likely to significantly increase costs and public choice risks’; see also R. Zimmermann, ‘Consumer Contract Law and General Contract Law: The German Experience’, 58 Current Legal Problems (2005) p. 415, at p. 458 et seq.

  85. Gsell and Schellhase, supra n. 2, at p. 27; Riehm and Schreindorfer, supra n. 6, at p. 249; Tamm, supra n. 6, at p. 760; Wilhelmsson, supra n. 6, at p. 227 (‘legal mess’).

  86. See H. Kötz, ‘Rechtsvereinheitlichung — Nutzen, Kosten, Methoden, Ziele’, 50 Rabels Zeitschrift für ausländisches und internationales Privatrecht (1996) p. 1, at p. 11; Möllers, supra n. 8, at p. 502; on harmonisation measures in general, but in particular on ‘high level regulatory centralisation’ in financial markets law, Moloney, supra n. 14, at p. 28, with n. 37.

    Google Scholar 

  87. See ESME, supra n. 46, at p. 5, marg. no. 4: ‘However, a major complaint among investors is the cost to investigate and report according to 27 systems cross Europe (and around 60 systems internationally) with differing approaches to what holdings are required to be reported, as well as when.’

  88. See the description of the general mood in Moloney, supra n. 14, at p. 34.

  89. Mazars, supra n. 39, at 3.1.1, p. 94: ‘It is when the stakeholders start expressing an opinion on more detailed or practical measures of the Directive that their dissatisfaction becomes visible. This is mainly due to the fact that the possibility for Member States to adopt more stringent requirements has undermined the Directive’s attempt to harmonise. To clarify: the Transparency Directive has not succeeded in simplifying the notification of major holdings in the EU. One of the consequences of the lack of harmonisation is that the burden to declare thresholds has not diminished despite the adoption of the Directive. It is a missed opportunity to reduce compliance costs.’ The study provides a detailed picture of the general opinions surveyed. See also the results of a further study carried out by CRA International, Evaluation of the Economic Impacts of the Financial Services Action Plan (March 2009), at p. 174; and the Commission Staff Working Document, supra n. 38, at Annex 5 sub D), p. 52 et seq.

  90. See Commission Staff Working Document, supra n. 31, at marg. no. 12, with n. 22, reporting that asset managers in particular have complained about the current level of legal fragmentation.

  91. See AMF, Promoting Better Regulation: Outcome of the Consultation (November 2010), at p. 10.

  92. For the (long-term) legislative goal of a ‘single rule book’ for financial services law in the EU and its contribution to uniform ownership disclosure requirements, see European Commission, supra n. 9, at p. 11. The creation of an integrated EU financial market was the stated goal of the FSAP Regulation: see Tison, supra n. 5, at p. 443 et seq. If nothing else, according to some authors the application of the minimum harmonisation approach to the Transparency Directive has limited its potential to reach its stated goals: see, for example, Moloney, supra n. 14, at p. 183 et seq.

  93. On these advantages, see Buchmann, supra n. 42, at p. 36, with additional references. Given that this entails the lowering of specific costs for investors who are active EU-wide, the legal basis for full harmonisation is provided by Art. 114(1) TFEU — under the condition that the measure brings actual cost benefits. The competence required for full harmonisation in financial markets law is covered in detail supra section 3.

  94. See Tison, supra n. 5, at p. 443 et seq.

  95. Generally on the (full) harmonisation of the ownership disclosure requirements in securities markets, see E. Ferran, Building an EU Securities Market (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press 2004), at p. 159: ‘The strongest potential justifications for these features [i.e. maximum or rigid minimum harmonisation] of the new issuer disclosure regime appear to lie in the achievement of more standard, and therefore more easily comparable, information relevant to investment decisions.’ In comparison, on the current regime under the Transparency Directive II, see European Commission, supra n. 9, at p. 11: ‘More stringent and additional rules at national level as well as provisions in the Directive allowing for derogations/discretion at national level results in an insufficient harmonisation level… The consequence of the lack of harmonisation and of unclear rules is that compliance costs are higher for investors and issuers and that disclosed information may not always be comparable.’ [emphasis added]

    Book  Google Scholar 

  96. See the 18th recital of the Transparency Directive II, supra n. 3.

  97. In this context, see European Commission, supra n. 9, at p. 11; sceptical with regard to adopting investor confidence as a core regulatory objective and political leitmotif for EU capital markets law, see also Moloney, supra n. 62.

  98. See generally A. Oehler, M. Rummer and S. Wendt, ‘Portfolio Selection of German Investors: On the Causes of Home-biased Investment Decisions’, 9 Journal of Behavioral Finance (2008) p. 149, with additional references.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  99. See Möllers, supra n. 8, at p. 503, who points to numerous studies that predict that harmonisation in the European securities market leads to positive growth; see also Moloney, supra n. 14, at p. 10 et seq.

  100. For a general view of the post-Financial Services Action Plan financial markets regime see Moloney, supra n. 14, at p. 4: ‘Following the completion of the FSAP in 2005 and an explosive reform period, the EC can now be regarded as the primary regulator of the EC’s financial market’, and at p. 46: ‘[T]he FSAP, in combination with the Lamfalussy process, has heavily diluted regulatory competition in the production of laws…’.

  101. See Mazars, supra n. 39, 3.1 (p. 94): ‘The fundamental principles of the Directive are not questioned.’ As stated earlier, this article is not intended to develop an ideal disclosure regime from scratch but builds on the regulatory status quo.

  102. In more detail, W.W. Bratton, J.A. McCahery and E.P.M. Vermeulen, ‘How Does Corporate Mobility Affect Lawmaking? A Comparative Analysis’, 57 American Journal of Comparative Law (2009) p. 347; H. Fleischer, in H. Fleischer and W. Goette, eds., Münchener Kommentar zum Gesetz betreffend die Gesellschaften mit beschränkter Haftung — GmbHG (Munich, C.H. Beck 2010), Introduction, marg. no. 227 et seq.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  103. S. Deakin, ‘Two Types of Regulatory Competition: Competitive Federalism versus Reflexive Harmonisation. A Law and Economics Perspective on Centros’, 2 Cambridge Yearbook of European Legal Studies (1999) p. 231, at p. 260; Ferran, supra n. 97, at p. 50 et seq.; see also Moloney, supra n. 14, at p. 10: ‘The minimum harmonisation model … in principle, accommodated flexibility, innovation, and, of particular importance in the EC context, local market sensitivity. [T]his model was not successful, however…’; Moloney, supra n. 8, at p. 1373 et seq.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  104. See Schouten, supra n. 8, at p. 180; see also J. Armour and D.A. Skeel, ‘Who Writes the Rules for Hostile Takeovers, and Why? — The Peculiar Divergence of U.S. and U.K. Takeover Regulation’, 95 The Georgetown Law Journal (2007) p. 1727, at p. 1750 et seq.

    Google Scholar 

  105. See also the Commission Staff Working Document, supra n. 38, at para. 26 in n. 76, according to which ‘more stringent national measures may be a driver of possible future convergence’.

  106. Fundamentally, D.C. North, Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press 1990), at p. 80 et seq.; the application thereof to capital markets, H. Fleischer and D. Zimmer, in H. Fleischer and D. Zimmer, eds., Effizienz als Regelungsziel im Handels- und Wirtschaftsrecht (Frankfurt a.M., Verlag Recht und Wirtschaft 2008) p. 9, at p. 15.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  107. Already discussed in Fleischer and Schmolke, supra n. 8, at p. 408.

  108. On the advantages of such a retrospective evaluation of legislative consequences, see the brief remarks by Schmolke, supra n. 43, at p. 918, in respect of the Lamfalussy process; see also Moloney, supra n. 14, at p. 29: ‘Paradoxically, it [i.e., regulatory competition] may also provide valuable evidence on how harmonization should proceed, where clear evidence emerges of market support of particular regulatory choices.’

  109. See generally, Schmolke, supra n. 43, at p. 912 et seq.

  110. See previously Fleischer and Schmolke, supra n. 8, at p. 408; now also in this vein, the recommendations in Mazars, supra n. 39, 3.1.7 (p. 97); and generally, K.U. Schmolke, ‘Die Einbeziehung des Komitologieverfahrens in den Lamfalussy-Prozess — Zur Forderung des Europäischen Parlaments nach mehr Entscheidungsteilhabe’, EuR (2006) p. 432, at p. 444 et seq.; for a contrasting opinion, see Thieme, supra n. 42, at p. 285, with additional references.

  111. Also to this effect, Mazars, supra n. 39, at 3.1.7, p. 97: ‘In order to ensure validity of the legislation over time, more market-resistant principles of transparency of ownership should be included in the Level 1 Directive and the harmonised figures and practical details specified in a Level 2 implementing measure under the Lamfalussy approach. In short, a better combination of Principle and Rules based approaches’; for a critique of the expanding regulatory stranglehold of the prevailing Level 1 Directives, see Schmolke, supra n. 112, at p. 446 et seq., with additional references; for an overview of the most recent developments in regulatory strategy at the EU level, following the financial crisis and taking into account the upcoming change in the regulatory architecture, Moloney, supra n. 8, at p. 1335 et seq.

  112. See Questions 19 and 20 cited from the Commission Consultation Document supra n. 9. In favour of the more frequent use of the regulation as a regulatory instrument, see Bachmann, supra n. 54, at p. 633. A survey has indicated that the majority of affected market participants across Europe favour more uniform regulation, while the majority of regulatory bodies are against it, see Mazars, supra n. 39, at 3.8.3.1, p. 147.

  113. Mazars, supra n. 39, at 3.1.7, p. 97.

  114. Ibid.

  115. See Commission Staff Working Document, supra n. 38, at para. 25.

  116. Commission Staff Working Document, supra n. 38, at para. 25, with n. 74 and Annex 7, as well as Question 22 in European Commission, supra n. 9, at p. 12.

  117. See also Clerc and Demarigny, supra n. 50, at p. 26, favouring the full harmonisation of these elements of the ownership disclosure regime.

  118. Particularities reflecting the law of individual Member States could of course still be taken into account in a standard form; see Mazars, supra n. 39, at 3.2.13, p. 98.

  119. See Art. 7 of the Commission Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council amending Directives 1998/26/EC, 2002/87/EC, 2003/6/EC, 2003/41/EC, 2003/71/EC, 2004/39/EC, 2004/109/EC, 2005/60/EC, 2006/48/EC, 2006/49/EC and 2009/65/EC in respect of the powers of the European Banking Authority, the European Insurance and Occupational Pensions Authority and the European Securities and Markets Authority, 26 October 2009, COM(2009) 576 final.

  120. See Mazars, supra n. 39, at 3.8.3, pp. 146–150; also Clerc and Demarigny, supra n. 50, at p. 27, speaking of a ‘simplification substantielle’.

  121. As already discussed in Fleischer and Schmolke, supra n. 8, at p. 409.

  122. It is only with regard to the annual financial reports — which are of no further interest to us here — as mentioned in Arts. 4–6 of the Directive and the obligation to disclose additional information of Art. 16 that Art. 7 requires Member States to provide for the responsibility and liability of the issuer or its administrative, management or supervisory bodies.

  123. Thus, M. Zimmermann, ‘Privatrecht im Kapitalmarktrecht der Gemeinschaft’, GPR (2008) p. 38, at p. 43; see also Zetzsche, supra n. 8, at p. 250.

  124. See Zetzsche, supra n. 8, p. 250: ‘Moreover, as enforcement is the practical aspect of law, enforcement measures need to be harmonised by regulation as well, in order to create the full benefit of harmonisation’; see also U. Noack and D.A. Zetzsche, ‘Verdeckter Positionsaufbau in börsennotierten Aktiengesellschaften — Anlegerschutz, Publizität, Enforcement’, in S. Grundmann, et al., eds., Unternehmensrecht zu Beginn des 21. Jahrhunderts, Festschriftfür Eberhard Schwark zum 70. Geburtstag (Munich, C.H. Beck 2009) p. 569, at p. 585 et seq.

  125. On the many problems this causes in German stock corporation law, see H. Fleischer and D. Bedkowski, ‘Stimmrechtszurechnung zum Treuhänder gemäß § 22I1 Nr. 2 WpHG: Ein zivilgerichtlicher Fehlgriff und seine kapitalmarktrechtlichen Folgen’, Deutsches Steuerrecht (2010) p. 933.

  126. See the Commission Staff Working Document, supra n. 38, at para. 26, p. 13: ‘reinforced harmonisation’. Earlier, the Commission had used the terms ‘adequate’ or ‘effective’ harmonisation, without explaining them further; see Tison, supra n. 5, at p. 449 et seq.

  127. The Commission Staff Working Document points out that the majority of affected market participants desire this, as also documented in the Mazars study, supra n. 39, at 3.3.2, p. 101.

  128. See, for example, European Commission, Communication of the Commission — Review of the Lamfalussy Process, Strengthening Supervisory Convergence, 20 November 2007, COM(2007) 727 final, at p. 5 sub 3.3; further, Commission Staff Working Document, supra n. 31, at paras. 22–24, to which the Commission Staff Working Document supra n. 38 refers explicitly with regard to its reinforced harmonisation approach, at para. 26, with nn. 78, 80 and 81.

  129. Suggested by Moloney, supra n. 14, at p. 27.

  130. Critical, however, of this differentiated approach, citing the lack of legal certainty and transparency, is Tison, supra n. 5, at p. 449 et seq. Yet these points can be countered by a sufficiently clear directive.

  131. On ‘incremental harmonisation’ in the context of matters of competence, see Roth, supra n. 5, at p. 24.

  132. Committee on the Internal Market and Consumer Protection, Draft Report, 25 June 2010, 2008/0196 COD (Rapporteur: A. Schwab), particularly in proposed amendment 59 (to Art. 4(1)) and its reasons, at p. 115; in depth on this new approach, H.-W. Micklitz, ‘The Targeted Full Harmonisation Approach: Looking Behind the Curtain’, in Howells and Schulze, eds., supra n. 2, at p. 47; critical of the actual dimensions this ‘targeted full harmonisation’ is taking in the context of the Directive on Consumer Rights, Stürner, supra n. 4; M. Loos, ‘Full Harmonization as a Regulatory Concept’, in M. Stürner, ed., Vollharmonisierung im Europäischen Verbraucherrecht? (Munich, Sellier, European law Publishers 2010), at pp. 47 and 87 et seqq.

  133. Reich, supra n. 75, at p. 38: ‘In order to render it more concrete, a new way of looking at what could be described as “half harmonisation” is being proposed, because it attempts to refine the usage of the “full” and “minimum” harmonisation principle. Thus, this is not a matter of either/or, i.e. “full” vs. “minimum” harmonization, but rather an “optimal” and “efficient” combination of various regulatory aims and levels…’; similarly, Howells and Schulze, eds., supra n. 2, at pp. 8 and 24.

  134. Commission Proposal, supra n. 4.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Fleischer, H., Schmolke, K.U. The Reform of the Transparency Directive: Minimum or Full Harmonisation of Ownership Disclosure?. Eur Bus Org Law Rev 12, 121–145 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1017/S156675291110004X

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/S156675291110004X

Keywords

Navigation