Verification
Estimation of the displaced gamma density
P12 assumesFootnote 4 a displaced gamma density for both \(T_H\) and \(\gamma \). Almost all the integrals for calculating WTP involve these two random variables. The results of the paper, therefore, depend heavily on this preliminary estimation. As in P12, we fit the parameters of a displaced gamma density for the random variable \(T_H\) with \({\mathbb {E}}(T_H)=3^\circ \)C, \({\mathbb {P}}(T_H\le 7^\circ C)=5\%\) and \({\mathbb {P}}(T_H\le 10^\circ C)=1\%\). We obtain \(r_{T}=3.9, \lambda _{T}=0.92\) and \(\theta _{T}=-1.22\), which can be compared with the values reported in P12: 3.8, 0.92 and \(-1.13\), respectively. Figure 1, that replicates Fig. 1 of P12, shows the two distributions which, in spite of the slightly different parameter values, appear to be almost indistinguishable.
The distribution of the damage coefficient \(\gamma \) is similarly calibrated, fitting a displaced gamma density such that \({\mathbb {E}}(\gamma )=0.0001363\), \({\mathbb {P}}(\gamma \le 0.0000450)=0.17\) and \({\mathbb {P}}(\gamma \le 0.0002295)=0.83\).Footnote 5
We obtain \(r_{\gamma }=4.43, \lambda _{\gamma }=20939\) and \(\theta _{\gamma }=-7.28\cdot 10^{-5}\). Our estimates are reasonably close to the values \(r_{\gamma }=4.50, \lambda _{\gamma }=21431\) and \(\theta _{\gamma }=-7.46\cdot 10^{-5}\) reported in P12, even though the numerical approximation of the parameters for \(\gamma \) was less trivial than for \(T_H\), due to the different orders of magnitude of the three parameters; for details, refer to “Discussion” section.
Estimation of willingness to pay
The main feature of P12 is the computation of several WTPs with different values taken by key parameters. WTP is displayed graphically in several figures, and also tabulated in two tables. In what follows, Figs. 2, 3 and 4 are the replications of Figs. 4, 5 and 6 of P12, respectively, while Table 1 is the replication of Table 1 of P12.
First, some benchmark WTPs are computed in a setup with no uncertainty on future temperature increase and economic impact; Fig. 2 depicts WTP \(w^*(0)\) to keep warming at zero as a function of a known \(T_H\), assuming a fixed value for \(\gamma ={\bar{\gamma }}={\mathbb {E}}(\gamma )=0.0001363\), and showing three possible scenarios for the growth rate \(g_0= 0.015\), 0.02 or 0.025 (the remaining parameters are the index of relative risk aversion \(\eta =2\) and the discount rate \(\delta =0\)). This is, therefore, a scenario with no uncertainty, where the integrals needed to evaluate WTP are one-dimensional. It is, of course, formally impossible to test whether two figures are the same, but an eyeball test of the twin figures in P12 and in this paper (and lots of zooming!) shows that they essentially display the very same quantities. Perhaps more concretely, to exemplify the meaning of Fig. 2, it is reported in P12 that when \(T=6\) and \(g_0=0.02\), then \(w^*(0)\) is about 0.022 or 2.2%. For comparison, our own computations produce 0.0216.
Second, WTPs are displayed in Fig. 3, allowing for uncertainty. In the diagram, the functions \(w^*(\tau )\) are depicted in four scenarios, combining different risk aversions \(\eta \) and baseline growth rates \(g_0\). Full three-dimensional integrals are involved in this setup, and care is needed to set apparently irrelevant (technical) parameters. It is again hard to discern any differences in the two versions of Fig. 3 from this paper and from Pindyck’s article.
Third, we focus on Fig. 4, where the dependence of \(w^*(3)\), namely the WTP required to limit the increase in temperature to \(3^\circ \)C, is plotted as a function of risk aversion \(\eta \) (under two different discount rates \(\delta \)). This diagram is interesting because it is difficult to replicate, particularly if \(\eta \) approaches 1 or when \(\eta =4\). In the first case, we have an evident singularity in the definition of \(U(\cdot )\), and can resort to the fact that, in this situation, the utility function is—up to a constant—a logarithmic function. It is less clear why high values of \(\eta \) prove to be relatively ill-posed for the integration routine cubature. While additional details are deferred to “Discussion” section, we observe that our Fig. 4 is extremely similar to the one presented in P12.
Finally, Table 1 lists 19 pairs of WTPs, and allows for a more rigorous comparison of the numeric figures obtained, tilting the reference values of some parameters. In particular, the two WTPs \(w^*(0)\) and \(w^*(3)\) are tabulated and, unless otherwise indicated, \(\delta =0\), \(\eta =2\), \(g_0=0.02\), \({\mathbb {E}}(T)=3^\circ C\), \({\mathbb {E}}(\gamma )=0.0001363\), and social utility is computed on a time span of 5 centuries (\(t_{max}=500\)).
Table 1 WTPs with alternative parameter values Some of our estimates of WTP (in the second and fourth columns) match those in P12 very well (placed side by side in the third and fifth columns). For instance, in the first row relative to the baseline case, the values of \(w^*(0)\) and \(w^*(3)\) differ by about \(5\cdot 10^{-4}\). In other cases, the gaps are insignificant from a practical and economic point of view, and give an idea of the “numeric noise” that affects (accurate) estimates obtained by different authors, with distinct software and code.
However, some noteworthy discrepancies can be seen in Rows 8, 16, 18 and 19. In Row 8, WTPs computed in P12 setting \(\eta =4\) and \(g_0=0.01\) are 30- or 60-fold larger than ours. Row 7 contains WTPs when the growth rate is 0.02 and, in agreement with intuition, halving the growth rate of the economy inflates the WTP to reduce the expected damage inflicted by climate change to weak economic growth. While, say, according to our computations, \(w^*(0)\) moves from 0.0015 in Row 7 to 0.0060 in Row 8 (a fourfold increase), in P12, we have a spectacular jump from 0.0014 to 0.1844. The same occurrence is visible for \(w^*(3)\). In Row 18, our \(w^*(0)\) and \(w^*(3)\) are quite smaller than WTPs in P12 (differences exceed 2 and 1% points, respectively).
These deviations cannot be attributed to slightly different computational methods being used in different packages, or to dissimilar settings of an abundance of default parameters that are used in standard routines for numerical computations.
Finally, the last row of Table 1 portrays a large difference in both WTPs. We suspect this is due to a material typing error in P12 since the entries in Pindyck’s table are exactly the same as in Row 10, whereas we expected the same figure of Row 9. As can be seen by looking at (8) of P12,Footnote 6 with \(\eta =2\) an increase in \(\delta \) compensates for a decrease in \(g_0\) of the same absolute value, implying that a scenario with \(\varepsilon (T_H)=5^\circ C\) and \(g_0=0.02\) is actually the same as a scenario where \(\varepsilon (T_H)=5^\circ C\), \(g_0=0.01\) and \(\delta =0.01\). For the same reason, the entries in Rows 1 and 16 in Table 1 should be the same, but this is not the case in P12.
All in all, while some of our estimates are close to the ones obtained by Pindyck, we were unable to replicate around one fifth of the figures in P12, and huge differences, in absolute and relative terms, cannot be explained by rounding or typing errors alone. An inspection of the MATLAB code kindly provided by Professor Pindyck shows that some of the reasons for the discrepancies may be related to an approximation of a triple integral with a summation of double integrals,Footnote 7 as well as the use of functions, such as dblquad and quad that are now—more than a decade after the original code was written—no longer recommended. Moreover, as we discuss in “Discussion” section, the results are unfortunately quite sensitive to apparently irrelevant parameters in several of the instances considered in P12. Such parameters, namely the upper extremes of integration, were hardwired in the code, and were not subject to a robustness test. In these cases, putting blind trust in the number crunching routines turned out to be unfortunate since essentially inaccurate estimates were generated.
Extension
This section provides an extension of the original paper where we change the data used to estimate densities for the temperature increase. As with every extension, since we change the data, the results shown here can obviously not be expected to resemble the ones in P12; instead, they should be used to assess how the original results are affected by the availability of new data. The IPCC’s Fifth Assessment Report (IPCC 2014), released in 2014, contains new data that can be used to estimate fresh densities for the uncertain quantities used in P12. In particular, IPCC (2014) describes four possible GHG scenarios, called representative concentration pathways (RCP), which are named after a possible range of radiative forcing values in 2081–2100 relative to pre-industrial values. The pathway without any GHG emissions mitigation effort beyond current legislation,Footnote 8 which can be considered as the baseline path for the present analysis, is RCP8.5;Footnote 9 the alternative scenarios, with increasing levels of mitigation and, therefore, decreasing levels of emissions, are RCP6.0, RCP4.5 and RCP2.6.
Under scenario RCP8.5, the forecast is a \(3.7^\circ C\) temperature increase from 1986–2005 to 2081–2100, with a “likely” range of \(2.6^\circ C\) to \(4.8^\circ C\). In Fig. 5, we extend Fig. 1 of P12 and we plot the “old” density for \(T_H\) and the “new” density, interpreting the term “likely” as a 66% or a 90% confidence interval (in P12, the term “likely” is viewed as 66%). Using the information \({\mathbb {E}}(T_H)=3.7^\circ C\), \({\mathbb {P}}(T_H\le 2.6^\circ C)=17\%\) and \({\mathbb {P}}(T_H\le 4.8^\circ C)=83\%\) to estimate the parameters of the gamma displaced density \(f_{2014}(x)\), we obtain \(r_{2014}=7.82\), \(\lambda _{2014}=2.38\) and \(\theta _{2014}=0.42\). Figure 5 shows that the distributions computed using more recent data shift to the right, and are more concentrated around the mean of 3.7\(^\circ \)C (and, in particular, the right tail is clearly much thinner than in P12 in both the versions obtained using 2014 data).
Observe that, with the new parameters, where \(\theta _{2014}=0.42\) is greater than zero, it is impossible to keep the temperature increment at 0 and, hence, \(w^*(0)\) cannot be estimated. Henceforth, in Table 2, we report WTPs for the same cases listed in Table 1, replacing \(w^*(0)\) with \(w^*(0.5)\), under the two interpretations of “likely”. In the third (sixth) column, we display \(w^*(0.5)\) (\(w^*(3)\)) for the various cases based on (IPCC 2007a, b, c); the fourth and fifth (seventh and eighth) columns show the values obtained from 2014 data.
Table 2 WTPs using alternative parameter values, IPCC (2014) data Looking at \(w^*(0.5)\), a scenario related to a stricter abatement policy, WTPs most often increase moving from 2007 to 2014 assessments, meaning that the newer IPCC report implies an upward revision of WTP to curb warming to \(0.5^\circ \) C. In any case, the differences in WTPs are modest, generally around 0.2–0.3% or less. Scenarios that assume \(\varepsilon (T_H)=5^\circ C\) imply a lower WTP under 2014 data. This is related to the lower standard deviation underlying the 2014 projections since, keeping the same expected value, a lower standard deviation implies a lower WTP, as explained in P12. Changes in the standard deviation of the temperature would also alter WTP in the baseline case of P12, with \(w^*(0)=0.0118\) and \(w^*(3)=0.0053\): halving (doubling) the standard deviation, which makes extreme events less (more) likely, would decrease (increase) WTPs to 0.0107 and 0.0025 (0.0132 and 0.0091), respectively. Columns 4 and 5 also show that WTPs are virtually the same, regardless of which interpretation of “likely” was chosen.
In contrast, examination of the columns relative to \(w^*(3)\) reveals that more recent data “suggest” a lower WTP for a moderate abatement policy (namely, limiting the temperature increment to \(3^\circ C\)). With respect to the WTP estimated using 2007 data, differences range from 0.1 to 1.8%. If “likely” means 90% confidence intervals, then, typically, WTPs are further reduced by an amount ranging between 0.1 and 0.7%.
Figures 6 and 7 are the counterparts (with more recent data) of Figs. 5 and 6 in P12. Careful inspection confirms the previous findings and comments, but, perhaps more importantly, may suggest that the inclusion of fresh data from 2014 appears to not have changed the gist of the conclusions and lessons learned from P12. It is true that temperature cannot be kept at the present level, and that strict (moderate) abatement policies are slightly more (less) worthwhile, but changes are perhaps minor in size in many circumstances of practical importance. This was somehow to be expected, after the marginal analysis in P12 already pointed out that a hike in the mean temperature would have been offset by a reduction in the standard deviation.