The direct impact of the pandemic on income distribution is closely associated to the fact that the spread of a deadly virus in a society leads to the death of a large number of workers, as poverty-stricken and low-income groups are most vulnerable to disease (Furceri et al. 2020; Galletta and Giommoni 2020). For example, results from a study carried out by Schmitt-Grohé et al. (2020) in the early stages of the spread of the SARS-CoV-2 virus in the United States suggest that the relative impact of the virus was far greater on poor communities compared to affluent ones. So far, studies have concluded that the economic and health impact of COVID-19 on the most vulnerable individuals—the poor, the homeless, etc.—has been much greater than on other sections of the population (Bell et al. 2020; Adams-Prassl et al. 2020; Alon et al. 2020). Moreover, the Great Influenza (1918–1920) witnessed very high mortality rates among workers (Brainerd and Siegler 2003). Consequently, a high mortality rate among workers leads to a scarcity of labor supply, resulting in higher wages (Alfani and Murphy 2017). Similarly, a pandemic can lead to the emergence of a production crisis and a reduction in consumption, as people tend to save more, and hence this directly affects the return on capital that the rich benefit from (the top 10% income share and above). Such a pandemic effect leads, therefore, to the narrowing of the income gap.
In his study, Cipolla (1964: p 524) argued that the Black Death might have been the leading cause in the redistribution of income through the increase of wages. Based on long-term data and evidence generated by a research on real wages (Pamuk 2007; Pamuk and Shatzmiller 2014), Alfani and Murphy (2017) corroborated Cipolla’s conclusion, arguing that labor scarcity led to increased real wages, narrowing the income gap. In their opinion, this was one of the direct effects of the Black Death on society. Moreover, these results refuted misconceptions on Black Death bringing about a rise in inequality (see Herlihy 1978).
The argument for the decline in inequality due to the pandemic is summarized in Fig. 1. It assumes that productivity remains constant, while the shock to the labor supply caused by the deadly pandemic (the Plague, for example) causes a decline in curve S–S′, which leads to an increase in the wages of those workers who survive the pandemic, from W to W′. This argument proposed by Capasso and Malanima (2007) was used by Li and Li (2017) in their study of the subsequent impact of the Plague that struck families immigrating to the Manchuria region in northern China in 1910–1911. The study examined a family that arrived in a village afflicted with the Plague and another that came to a neighboring village, free of the Plague. The study found that the wages of the first family were higher than those of the second family. To explain this difference, researchers used the classical economic theory of supply and demand (see Fig. 1). For a clearer illustration, consider that two villages had the same wage level before the Plague. In the town affected by the Plague, the ensuing deaths and the delayed arrival of seasonal migrants lead to a decrease in the labor supply, thus shifting the supply curve from S to S′. As a result, wages in this town increase from W to W′. Meanwhile, wage levels remain unaffected in the town that is not affected by the Plague.
However, this assumption cannot be generalized to all pandemics. Productivity itself is not always stable since pandemics may lead to a decline in productivity. Alfani and Percoco (2016) argue that there is no reason to assume that every pandemic (defining the Plague) positively impacts wages because the ultimate effect depends on the magnitude of the labor supply shock relative to the productivity shock caused by the pandemic. This can be shown in Fig. 2, where the shock in productivity shifts the curve for labor demand from D to D′, leading to a decrease, stability, or a rise in wages. Therefore, if curve D falls below curve S, we should expect the pandemic to result in higher wages. The opposite will result in lower wages.
Accordingly, the pandemic’s subsequent effects on income inequality may differ according to the characteristics of the pandemic itself. Consequently, it cannot be inferred that every pandemic leads to a decrease in inequality. In this context, Alfani (2015) and Alfani and Ammannati (2017) assert that although in the very long term, inequality has always shown a tendency to rise, the Black Death was the only recorded event that led to a decrease in income inequality in northwest Italy in the period of 1300–1800, as compared to other epidemiological events that did not reduce inequality. In fact, since the seventeenth century, events with a high death toll have had entirely different effects from those of the Black Death. Based on that, Alfani (2015) concluded that the ensuing effects of different plague pandemics on inequality levels were not the same; a plague pandemic can decrease (as the effect of Black Death) or increase income inequality (e.g., the 1629–1630 Plagues).
The effects of the Black Death in Italy are similar to those of Spain. Álvarez-Nogal and De La Escosura (2013) provided historical data dating back to the year 1200 (see Fig. 3) and showing the levels of income inequality in Spain in the very long term. Based on this data, Milanovic (2016) concluded that income inequality declined due to the Black Death, and wages in northwestern Europe increased significantly because of this pandemic.
This result is confirmed in England by Clark (2007, 2010); there, the Black Death led to a decrease in the labor supply by 25–40%, while real wages rose by almost 100%. In parallel, this pandemic decreased the rates of return on land from 5% to around 8%. As for Jordà et al. (2020), they examined the macroeconomic cost of 15 pandemics, particularly the return rates on assets, based on data dating back to the fourteenth century. Their study found that the after-effects of a pandemic can last for up to four decades, during which the natural rate of interest drops drastically (1.5%), and in the same period, real wages rise by up to 5%. The study also concludes that the real wages’ response mirrors that of the natural interest rate (which also measures the return on capital). Their findings coincide with the neoclassical model’s predictions and are also consistent with historical narratives. In fact, one of the Black Death effects was labor scarcity in the European economies, which is believed to have led to the rise in real wages. In parallel, this was accompanied by lower returns on capital.
The Black Death’s income effects are not much different from another grave pandemic that spread worldwide between 1918 and 1920—the Great Influenza. The results of Jordà et al. (2020), which included the Great Influenza, confirm that each pandemic with a death toll of more than 100 thousand people can positively impact reducing disparities in income. However, the 1918–1920 Flu virus, which wiped out 2% of the world’s population at the time, manifested unique features and had a far greater impact on inequality than other pandemics. The age curve of mortality took a “W” shape for the Spanish flu, meaning that the number of deaths among individuals aged between 15 and 44 years was high, in contrast to the “U-shaped” mortality curve of the influenza virus (Brainerd and Siegler 2003).
In addition to this factor, Barro et al. (2020) found that the high mortality rates of the Great Influenza led to a decrease in real per capita consumption by 8%, while real returns on stocks and short-term government bonds decreased drastically. Therefore, based on the modern economic theory on labor scarcity and under-consumption mentioned previously (see also Ramsey 1928; Rachel and Smith 2017; Jordà et al. 2020), it is likely that the Great Influenza contributed to a reduction in income inequality.
However, it is important to note that the literature on the impact of pandemics on inequality is still scarce, probably due to the relative scarcity of pandemics in the past 100 years. As for empirical research examining the relationship between income inequality and pandemics, Alfani (2015) and Alfani and Ammannati (2017) studied the impact of pandemics in some Italian cities during the pre-industrial era and concluded that the Black Death had a fundamental role in the decline of inequality in Italy. However, Galletta and Giommoni (2020) who studied the impact of the Great Influenza on inequality in Italian towns, concluded that in both short and medium terms, income inequality would increase in the towns that were most affected by the pandemic, due to the decrease in the income share held by the poor.
An additional reference for our study is that of Furceri et al. (2020), who studied the impact of five epidemics that appeared in the past 20 years (2000–2020), namely SARS 2003, H1N1 2009, MERS 2012, Ebola 2014, and Zika 2016. In contrast to other spreads, these events had a relatively weak impact on the economy and society: only a few countries were affected, and the mortality rate was moderately low compared to previous pandemicsFootnote 3––the 2009 pandemic was the only exception. Furceri et al. (2020) found that these events led to a rise in inequality in the countries covered by the research. In conclusion, we believe that the characteristics of the viruses that have spread in the last two decades make it difficult to draw general conclusions about pandemics’ impact on inequality.