Skip to main content
Log in

Cognitive perspectives on opinion dynamics: the role of knowledge in consensus formation, opinion divergence, and group polarization

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Journal of Computational Social Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Two phenomena that are central to simulation research on opinion dynamics are opinion divergence—the result that individuals interacting in a group do not always collapse to a single viewpoint, and group polarization—the result that average group opinions can become more extreme after discussions than they were to begin with. Standard approaches to modeling these dynamics have typically assumed that agents have an influence bound, such that individuals ignore opinions that differ from theirs by more than some threshold, and thus converge to distinct groups that remain uninfluenced by other distinct beliefs. Additionally, models have attempted to account for group polarization either by assuming the existence of recalcitrant extremists, who draw others to their view without being influenced by them, or negative reaction—movement in opinion space away from those they disagree with. Yet these assumptions are not well supported by existing social/cognitive theory and data, and insofar as there are data, it is often mixed. Moreover, an alternative cognitive assumption is able to produce both of these phenomena: the need for consistency within a set of related beliefs. Via simulation, we show that assumptions about knowledge or belief spaces and conceptual coherence naturally produce both convergence to distinct groups and group polarization, providing an alternative cognitively grounded mechanism for these phenomena.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Complete source code for these simulations is available at https://www.openabm.org/model/5808/version/1/view, and hypothetical interaction in a simple system is described in the Appendix.

References

  1. Brush, S. G. (1967). History of the Lenz-Ising model. Reviews of Modern Physics, 39(4), 883–893.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Sznajd-Weron, K., & Sznajd, J. (2000). Opinion evolution in closed community. International Journal of Modern Physics C-Physics and Computer, 11(6), 1157–1166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Castellano, C., Fortunato, S., & Loreto, V. (2009). Statistical physics of social dynamics. Reviews of Modern Physics, 81(2), 591–646.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Martins, A. C. (2015). Opinion particles: classical physics and opinion dynamics. Physics Letters A, 379(3), 89–94.

  5. Sobkowicz, P. (2009). Modelling opinion formation with physics tools: Call for closer link with reality. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 12(1), 11. http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/12/1/11.html.

  6. Weisbuch, G., & Stauffer, D. (2000). Hits and flops dynamics. Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, 287(3–4), 563–576.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Anderson, L. R., & Holt, C. A. (1997). Information cascades in the laboratory. The American Economic Review, 87(5), 847–862.

  8. Mackay, C. (1852). Memoirs of Extraordinary Popular Delusions and the Madness of Crowds. London: Office of the National Illustrated Library. http://www.gutenberg.org/ebooks/24518.

  9. DeGroot, M. H. (1974). Reaching a consensus. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 69(345), 118–121. http://www.jstor.org/stable/2285509.

  10. Parunak, H. V. Belding, T. C. Hilscher, R., & Brueckner, S. (2008). Modeling and managing collective cognitive convergence. In: Proceedings of the 7th international joint conference on Autonomous agents and multiagent systems—Volume 3, International Foundation for Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems (pp. 1505–1508), Estoril, Portugal. http://portal.acm.org/citation.cfm?id=1402821.1402910.

  11. Parunak, H.(2009). A mathematical analysis of collective cognitive convergence. In: Proceedings of The 8th International Conference on Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems-Volume 1, International Foundation for Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems (pp. 473–480).

  12. Lorenz, J. (2007). Continuous opinion dynamics under bounded confidence: A survey. International Journal of Modern Physics C, 18(12), 1819–1838.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Axelrod, R. (1997). The dissemination of culture: A model with local convergence and global polarization. The Journal of Conflict Resolution, 41(2), 203–226. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/174371.

  14. Amblard, F., & Deffuant, G. (2004). The role of network topology on extremism propagation with the relative agreement opinion dynamics. Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, 343, 725–738.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Carletti, T., Fanelli, D., Grolli, S., & Guarino, A. (2006). How to make an efficient propaganda. Europhysics Letters, 74(2), 222–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Deffuant, G. (2006). Comparing extremism propagation patterns in continuous opinion models. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 9(3), 8. http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/9/3/8.html.

  17. Deffuant, G., Neau, D., & Amblard, F. (2000). Mixing beliefs among interacting agents. Advances in Complex Systems, 3, 87–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Deffuant, G., Amblard, F., Weisbuch, G., & Faure, T. (2002). How can extremism prevail? A study based on the relative agreement interaction model. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 5(4).

  19. Fortunato, S. (2005) Monte Carlo simulations of opinion dynamics. In Complexity, metastability and nonextensivity. Proceedings of the 31st workshop of the international school of solid state physics (pp. 301–305). Erice, Sicily, Italy, 20–26 July 2004. https://doi.org/10.1142/9789812701558_0034.

  20. Fortunato S., Stauffer D. (2006) Computer simulations of opinions and their reactions to extreme events. In: S. Albeverio, V. Jentsch, H. Kantz (Eds) Extreme events in nature and society. The Frontiers Collection. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/3-540-28611-X_11.

  21. Franks, D. W., Noble, J., Kaufmann, P., & Stagl, S. (2008). Extremism propagation in social networks with hubs. Adaptive Behavior, 16(4), 264–274.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Gómez-Serrano, J., Graham, C., & Le Boudec, J.-Y. (2012). The bounded confidence model of opinion dynamics. Mathematical Models and Methods in Applied Sciences, 22(02), 1150007. http://www.worldscientific.com/doi/abs/10.1142/S0218202511500072.

  23. Groeber, P., Schweitzer, F. & Press, K. (2009). How groups can foster consensus: The case of local cultures. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 12(2), 4. http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/12/2/4.html.

  24. Hegselmann, R. K., & Krause, U. (2002). Opinion dynamics and bounded confidence models, analysis and simulation. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation 5(3). http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/5/3/2.html.

  25. Lorenz, J. (2006). Consensus strikes back in the Hegselmann-Krause model of continuous opinion dynamics under bounded confidence. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 9(1), 8. http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/9/1/8.html.

  26. Lorenz, J. (2006). Continuous opinion dynamics of multidimensional allocation problems under bounded confidence: More dimensions lead to better chances for consensus. European Journal of Economic and Social Systems, 19(2), 213–227.

  27. Lorenz J. (2008) Fostering consensus in multidimensional continuous opinion dynamics under bounded confidence. In: D. Helbing (Ed) Managing Complexity: Insights, Concepts, Applications. Understanding Complex Systems. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer

  28. Lorenz, J. (2010). Heterogeneous bounds of confidence: Meet, discuss and find consensus! Complexity, 15(4), 43–52.

    Google Scholar 

  29. Urbig, D. & Malitz, R. (2005). Dynamics of structured attitudes and opinions. In: K. G. Troitzsch (Ed.) Representing social reality. Pre-Proceedings of the Third Conference of the European Social Simulation Association (ESSA), (pp. 206–212) September 5–9, Koblenz, Germany, 2005. https://www.researchgate.net/profile/Diemo_Urbig/publication/228360096_Dynamics_of_structured_attitudes_and_opinions/links/00b4952ff206292534000000.pdf.

  30. Urbig, D., & Malitz, R. (2007). Drifting to more extreme but balanced attitudes: Multidimensional attitudes and selective exposure. Presented at the Fourth Conference of the European Social Simulation Association (ESSA), September 10–14, Toulouse.

  31. Deffuant, G., Amblard, F., Weisbuch, G. (2004). Modelling group opinion shift to extreme: The smooth bounded confidence model. Presented to the 2nd ESSA Conference (Valladolid, Spain), September 2004.

  32. Dittmer, J. C. (2001). Consensus formation under bounded confidence. Nonlinear Analysis-Theory Methods and Applications 47(7), 4615–4622.

  33. Chacoma, A., & Zanette, D. H. (2015). Opinion formation by social influence: From experiments to modeling. PLoS One, 10(10), 1–16. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0140406.

  34. Moussaïd, M., Kämmer, J. E., Analytis, P. P., & Neth, H. (2013). Social influence and the collective dynamics of opinion formation. PloS One, 8(11), e78433.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Mueller, S. T., & Weidemann, C. T. (2008). Decision noise: An explanation for observed violations of signal detection theory. Psychonomic Bulletin & Review, 15(3), 465–494.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  36. Tajfel, H. (1970). Experiments in intergroup discrimination. Scientific American, 223(5), 96–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. Mark, N. P. (2003). Culture and competition: Homophily and distancing explanations for cultural niches. American Sociological Review, 68(3), 319–345.

  38. Lazarsfeld, P. F., & Merton, R. K. (1954). Friendship as a social process: A substantive and methodological analysis. Freedom and Control in Modern Society, 18(1), 18–66.

    Google Scholar 

  39. Ferguson, C. K., & Kelley, H. H. (1964). Significant factors in overevaluation of own-group’s product. The Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology, 69(2), 223–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. Brewer, M. B. (1979). In-group bias in the minimal intergroup situation: A cognitive-motivational analysis. Psychological Bulletin, 86(2), 307–324.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  41. Festinger, L. (1954). A theory of social comparison processes. Human Relations, 7(2), 117–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. Schachter, S. (1951). Deviation, rejection, and communication. The Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology, 46(2), 190–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  43. Wesselmann, E. D., Williams, K. D., Pryor, J. B., Eichler, F. A., Gill, D. M., & Hogue, J. D. (2014). Revisiting Schachter’s research on rejection, deviance, and communication (1951). Social Psychology, 45, 164–169.

  44. Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1973). On the psychology of prediction. Psychological Review, 80(4), 237–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  45. Wegener, D. T., Petty, R. E., Detweiler-Bedell, B. T., & Jarvis, W. B. G. (2001). Implications of attitude change theories for numerical anchoring: Anchor plausibility and the limits of anchor effectiveness. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 37(1), 62–69. http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/B6WJB-457D4HT-1P/2/d9483e5c9920370da94c9ae37c5dde3f.

  46. Englich, B. (2006). Blind or biased? Justitia’s susceptibility to anchoring effects in the courtroom based on given numerical representations. Law and Policy, 28(4), 497–514.

    Google Scholar 

  47. Hayes, A. M., Laurenceau, J.-P., Feldman, G., Strauss, J. L., & Cardaciotto, L. (2007). Change is not always linear: The study of nonlinear and discontinuous patterns of change in psychotherapy. Clinical Psychology Review, 27(6), 715–723. http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/B6VB8-4MVN14D-6/2/2d0ad304286a16fd4037c8d399dd6a30.

  48. Long, T. E., & Hadden, J. K. (1983). Religious conversion and the concept of socialization: Integrating the brainwashing and drift models. Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion, 22(1), 1–14. http://www.jstor.org/discover/10.2307/1385588?uid=3739976&uid=2&uid=4&uid=3739256&sid=21102621604543.

  49. Kerckhove, C. V., Martin, S., Gend, P., Rentfrow, P. J., Hendrickx, J. M., & Blondel, V. D. (2016). Modelling influence and opinion evolution in online collective behaviour. PloS One, 11(6), e0157685.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  50. Takács, K., Flache, A., & Mäs, M. (2016). Discrepancy and disliking do not induce negative opinion shifts. PLoS One, 11(6), 1–21. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0157948.

  51. Pariser, E. (2011). The Filter Bubble: What the Internet is Hiding From You. New York: Penguin Press.

  52. Huber, D. E., Shiffrin, R. M., Quach, R., & Lyle, K. B. (2002). Mechanisms of source confusion and discounting in short-term priming: 1. Effects of prime duration and prime recognition. Memory & Cognition, 30(5), 745–757.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  53. Mueller, S. T. (2009). A Bayesian recognitional decision model. Journal of Cognitive Engineering and Decision Making, 3(2), 111–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  54. Bush, J. G., Johnson, H. M., & Seifert, C. M. (1994). The implications of corrections: Then why did you mention it? In: Proceedings of the Sixteenth Annual Conference of the Cognitive Science Society: August 13-16, 1994. Georgia Institute of Technology (p. 112). Lawrence Erlbaum Associates.

  55. Simpkins, B., Sieck, W. R., Smart, P. R., & Mueller, S. T. (2010). Idea Propagation in Social Networks: The Role of ‘Cognitive Advantage’. First ITA Workshop on Network-Enabled Cognition: The Contribution of Social and Technological Networks to Human Cognition, Maryland, USA.

  56. Dykstra, P., Elsenbroich, C., Jager, W., Renardel de Lavalette, G., & Verbrugge, R. (2013). Put your money where your mouth is: DIAL, a dialogical model for opinion dynamics. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 16(3), 4. http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/16/3/4.html.

  57. Fraser, C. (1971). Group risk-taking and group polarization. European Journal of Social Psychology, 1(4), 493–510.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  58. Myers, D. G., & Lamm, H. (1976). The group polarization phenomenon. Psychological Bulletin, 83(4), 602–627.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  59. Baldassarri, D., & Bearman, P. (2007). Dynamics of political polarization. American Sociological Review, 72(5), 784–811.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  60. Isenberg, D. J. (1986). Group polarization: A critical review and meta-analysis. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 50(6), 1141–1151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  61. Weisbuch, G., Deffuant, G., Amblard, F., & Nadal, J. P. (2002). Meet, discuss, and segregate! Complexity, 7(3), 55–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  62. Weisbuch, G., Deffuant, G., Amblard, F., & Nadal, J. P. (2001). Interacting agents and continuous opinions dynamics. Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems, 521, 225–242. http://wwwlisc.clermont.cemagref.fr/MembresEtPagesIntermediaires/pagesperso/anciens_membres/amblard_frederic/ressources/2001/WeisbuchSpringer.ps.

  63. Xie, J., Sreenivasan, S., Korniss, G., Zhang, W., Lim, C., & Szymanski, B. K. (2011). Social consensus through the influence of committed minorities. Physical Review E, 84(1), 011130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  64. Martins, A. C., & Galam, S. (2013). Building up of individual inflexibility in opinion dynamics. Physical Review E, 87(4), 042807.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  65. Kou, G., Zhao, Y., Peng, Y., & Shi, Y. (2012). Multi-level opinion dynamics under bounded confidence. PloS One, 7(9), e43507.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  66. Weisbuch, G., Deffuant, G., & Amblard, F. (2005). Persuasion dynamics. Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, 353, 555–575.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  67. Salzarulo, L. (2006). A continuous opinion dynamics model based on the principle of meta-contrast. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 9(1), 13. http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/9/1/13.html.

  68. Yildiz, E., Acemoglu, D., Ozdaglar, A. E., Saberi, A., & Scaglione, A. (2011). Discrete opinion dynamics with stubborn agents. Tech. rep., MIT. https://www.researchgate.net/publication/228305965_Binary_Opinion_Dynamics_with_Stubborn_Agents.

  69. Acemoğlu, D., Como, G., Fagnani, F., & Ozdaglar, A. (2013). Opinion fluctuations and disagreement in social networks. Mathematics of Operations Research, 38(1), 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  70. Flache, A., & Torenvlied, R. (2001). Persistent instability in polarized opinion formation and collective decision-making. The Fourth Summer School on Polarization and Conflict, July 23–27, 2001, San Sebastián, Spain. http://www.ppsw.rug.nl/~flache/chaosNew.pdf.

  71. Guazzini, A., Cini, A., Bagnoli, F., & Ramasco, J. (2015). Opinion dynamics within a virtual small group: The stubbornness effect. Frontiers in Physics, 3, 65. http://journal.frontiersin.org/article/10.3389/fphy.2015.00065.

  72. O’Keefe, D. J. (2002). Persuasion: Theory and Research, Vol. 2. Thousand Oaks: Sage Publications.

  73. Cattell, R. B., Eber, H. W., & Tatsuoka, M. M. (1988). Handbook for the Sixteen Personality Factor Questionnaire (16 PF). Illinois: Institute for Personality and Ability Testing Champaign.

  74. Barrick, M. R., & Mount, M. K. (1991). The big five personality dimensions and job performance: A meta-analysis. Personnel Psychology, 44(1), 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  75. Carney, D. R., Jost, J. T., Gosling, S. D., & Potter, J. (2008). The secret lives of liberals and conservatives: Personality profiles, interaction styles, and the things they leave behind. Political Psychology, 29(6), 807–840.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  76. Shook, N. J., & Fazio, R. H. (2009). Political ideology, exploration of novel stimuli, and attitude formation. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 45(4), 995–998.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  77. Jost, J. T., & Amodio, D. M. (2012). Political ideology as motivated social cognition: Behavioral and neuroscientific evidence. Motivation and Emotion, 36(1), 55–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  78. Sherif, M., & Hovland, C. I. (1961). Social judgment: Assimilation and contrast effects in communication and attitude change. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  79. Schwarz, N., Strack, F., & Mai, H.-P. (1991). Assimilation and contrast effects in part-whole question sequences: A conversational logic analysis. Public Opinion Quarterly, 55(1), 3–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  80. Wood, W., Pool, G. J., Leck, K., & Purvis, D. (1996). Self-definition, defensive processing, and influence: The normative impact of majority and minority groups. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 71(6), 1181–1193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  81. Fromkin, H. L. (1970). Effects of experimentally aroused feelings of undistinctiveness upon valuation of scarce and novel experiences. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 16(3), 521–529.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  82. Kaplan, M. (1977). Discussion polarization effects in a modified jury decision paradigm: informational influences. Sociometry, 40(3), 262–271. https://doi.org/10.2307/3033533.

  83. Flache, A., & Macy, M. W. (2006). Why more contact may increase cultural polarization. arXiv preprint physics/0604196. http://arxiv.org/abs/physics/0604196.

  84. Huet, S., Deffuant, G., & Jager, W. (2008). A rejection mechanism in 2D bounded confidence provides more conformity. Advances in Complex Systems, 11(04), 529–549.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  85. Huet, S., & Deffuant, G. (2010). Openness leads to opinion stability and narrowness to volatility. Advances in Complex Systems, 13(03), 405–423.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  86. Jager, W., & Amblard, F. (2005). Uniformity, bipolarization and pluriformity captured as generic stylized behavior with an agent-based simulation model of attitude change. Computational & Mathematical Organization Theory, 10(4), 295–303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  87. Jager, W., & Amblard, F. (2005). Multiple attitude dynamics in large populations. In: Agent 2005 Conference on Generative Social Processes, Models, and Mechanisms (pp. 595–613).

  88. Jager, W., & Amblard, F. (2007). Guess you’re right on this one too: Central and peripheral processing in attitude changes in large populations. In: Advancing Social Simulation: The First World Congress (pp. 249–260). New York: Springer.

  89. Radillo-Díaz, A., Pérez, L. A., & del Castillo-Mussot, M. (2009). Axelrod models of social influence with cultural repulsion. Physical Review E, 80(6), 066107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  90. Sobkowicz, P. (2012). Discrete model of opinion changes using knowledge and emotions as control variables. PLoS One, 7(9), e44489.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  91. Sobkowicz, P. (2015). Extremism without extremists: Deffuant model with emotions. Frontiers in Physics, 3, 17. http://journal.frontiersin.org/article/10.3389/fphy.2015.00017.

  92. Jalili, M. (2013). Social power and opinion formation in complex networks. Physica A: Statistical mechanics and its applications, 392(4), 959–966.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  93. Jalili, M. (2013). Effects of leaders and social power on opinion formation in complex networks. Simulation, 89(5), 578–588.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  94. Malarz, K., Gronek, P., & Kulakowski, K. (2011). Zaller-Deffuant model of mass opinion. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 14(1).

  95. Dykstra, P., Elsenbroich, C., Jager, W., Renardel de Lavalette, G. & Verbrugge, R. (2010). A logicbased architecture for opinion dynamics. In: A. Ernst, S. Kuhn (Eds.) Proceeding of the 3rd World Congress on Social Simulation, WCSS2010. (CD-ROM) Centre for Environmental Systems Research, University of Kassel, Germany.

  96. Deffuant, G., Carletti, T. and Huet, S. (2013). The Leviathan model: Absolute dominance, generalised distrust, small worlds and other patterns emerging from combining vanity with opinion propagation. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 16(1), 5. https://doi.org/10.18564/jasss.2070.

  97. Sîrbu, A. Loreto, V., Servedio, V. D. P., & Tria, F. (2013). Opinion dynamics with disagreement and modulated information. Journal of Statistical Physics, 151(1–2), 218–237. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10955-013-0724-x.

  98. Landauer, T. K., & Dumais, S. T. (1997). A solution to Plato’s problem: The latent semantic analysis theory of acquisition, induction, and representation of knowledge. Psychological Review, 104(2), 211–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  99. Tversky, A. (1977). Features of similarity. Psychological Review, 84(4), 327–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  100. Martin, S., Deffuant, G., Nadal, J. P., & Weisbuch, G. (2004). Comparing the binary opinion vector version of the BC model with different approximating aggregated dynamics. In: 2nd Model-to-Model Workshop, 2nd International Conference of the European Social Simulation Association, Sept 16–19, 2004, Valladolid, Spain.

  101. Macy, M. W., Flache, A., & Takacs, K. (2006). What sustains stable cultural diversity and what undermines it? Axelrod and beyond. In: S. Takahashi (Ed.), Advancing Social Simulation: Proceedings of the First World Congress on Social Simulation (pp. 9–16). Kyoto, Japan: Springer.

  102. Maletić, S., & Rajković, M. (2009). Simplicial complex of opinions on scale-free networks. In: Complex Networks (pp. 127–134). New York: Springer.

  103. Maletić, S., & Rajković, M. (2014). Consensus formation on a simplicial complex of opinions. Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, 397, 111–120.

  104. Murphy, G. L., & Medin, D. L. (1985). The role of theories in conceptual coherence. Psychological Review, 92(3), 289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  105. Mueller, S. T., & Veinott, E. S. (2008). Cultural mixture modeling: Identifying cultural consensus (and disagreement) using finite mixture modeling. In: Proceedings of the 30th Annual Conference of the Cognitive Science Society (pp. 64–70).

  106. Cook, K. J. (1998). A passion to punish: Abortion opponents who favor the death penalty. Justice Quarterly, 15(2), 329–346.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  107. Mueller, S. T., Simpkins, & B., Rasmussen, L. (2010). Incorporating representation when modeling cultural dynamics: Analysis of the bounded influence conjecture. In: Proceedings of the Workshop on Cognitive Social Sciences: Grounding the Social Sciences in the Cognitive Sciences (pp. 29–34).

  108. Mueller, S. T., & Shiffrin, R. M., (2006). REM II: A model of the developmental co-evolution of episodic memory and semantic knowledge. In: International Conference on Learning and Development (ICDL), Bloomington, IN.

  109. Thanasuan, K., & Mueller, S. T. (2014). Crossword expertise as recognitional decision making: An artificial intelligence approach. Frontiers in Psychology, 5, 1018. https://doi.org/10.3389/fpsyg.2014.01018.

  110. Doignon, J., & Falmagne, J. (1985). Spaces for the assessment of knowledge. International Journal of Man-Machine Studies, 23(2), 175–196. http://linkinghub.elsevier.com/retrieve/pii/S0020737385800316.

  111. Butts, C. T., & Hilgeman, C. (2003). Inferring potential memetic structure form cross-sectional data: An application to American religious beliefs. Journal of Memetics: Evolutionary Models of Information Transmission, 7(2), 12–34.

    Google Scholar 

  112. Doignon, J., & Falmagne, J. (1999). Knowledge Spaces. New York: Springer-Verlag.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  113. Wiley, J. A., & Martin, J. L. (1999). Algebraic representations of beliefs and attitudes: Partial order models for item responses. Sociological Methodology 29, 113–146. http://www.jstor.org/stable/271120.

  114. Martin, J. L., & Wiley, J. A. (2000). Algebraic representations of beliefs and attitudes II: Microbelief models for dichotomous belief data. Sociological Methodology, 30, 123–164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  115. McGarty, C., Turner, J. C., Hogg, M. A., David, B., & Wetherell, M. S. (1992). Group polarization as conformity to the prototypical group member. British Journal of Social Psychology, 31(1), 1–19. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.2044-8309.1992.tb00952.x.

  116. Watts, D. J., & Strogatz, S. H. (1998). Collective dynamics of ‘small-world’ networks. Nature, 393(6684), 440.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  117. Giardini, F., Vilone, D., & Conte, R. (2015). Consensus emerging from the bottom-up: the role of cognitive variables in opinion dynamics. Frontiers in Physics, 3, 64. http://journal.frontiersin.org/article/10.3389/fphy.2015.00064.

  118. Thiriot, S., & Kant, J.-D. (2008). Using associative networks to represent adopters’ beliefs in a multiagent model of innovation diffusion. Advances in Complex Systems, 11(02), 261–272.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Some of the research reported here was performed under Subcontract No. RQ000746 from SRA International, Inc. (Prime contract contract FA8650-09-D-6939) in support of the Air Force Research Labs, Wright-Patterson Air Force Base, OH. The author would like to thank Dr. Michael J. Young with AFRL for his encouragement, guidance, and support.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Shane T. Mueller.

Appendix: example interaction of model

Appendix: example interaction of model

To clarify the workings of this model, let us suppose that a domain contained five binary features. This could support \(2^5=32\) distinct knowledge states, but because of logic or tradition, we might suppose that just five exist in the knowledge space lattice: 00000, 10000, 01000, 11110, and 11111. In the simulation, two agents might begin in any of these five states, and any change in belief must occur between one of these five states. The different simulations in this paper described different ways in which this initial distribution can be chosen. The critical assumption is that not all states are coherent—some features may be, by tradition or logic, inconsistent with others, meaning that to transition between states, multiple beliefs must be changed.

In the simulation, each interaction progresses by selecting two agents at random. Thus, interaction is not constrained by homophily, geography, or group status. Although each of these is likely to constrain interactions in real-world situations, we elected to not incorporate them to determine whether knowledge structure alone could produce the results we observed. For each member of the pair, a candidate belief was generated by changing each feature to the other member’s value with probability \(\mu \) (which was typically set to 0.3 for these simulations). If the two agents agreed on a feature, no change in belief was possible. The changes happened in parallel, so it would be possible in some circumstances for two agents to completely exchange belief states. For example, suppose an agent at state 10000 met an agent at state 01000. In this case, for each agent, the only possible outcome states would be 10000, 01000, 11000, and 00000. However, in the belief space we are considering, 11000 is not a coherent belief. This is simply an exclusive OR; someone may support one approach or another approach to solving a problem; but not both. This could be something like economic policy, in which one group believes raising taxes will increase tax revenue and reduce debt, whereas another group believes lowering taxes will grow the economy and reduce debt. The comparison is done on the agents original states; transitions to new candidate states happens only after interaction. Once the new candidate state is identified for each agent, the agent will only transition to that new state if it is coherent and thus exists in the belief space lattice. If it does not exist, the agent will remain at its original belief state.

The basic exchange routine is as follows:

figure a

As another example, suppose again that Agent 1 is in belief state 10000, and Agent 2 is in state 01000. They disagree on two issues, but each might be convinced to move to the nearby state 00000, which is more extreme than either of them began. This would produce a polarization effect. Although the same interaction could lead either of them to consider moving to 11000, in this belief space that belief state does not exist and so neither could move there. Again, an example of this might be a simple XOR belief; someone may support higher property taxes if it is used for education (10000), or if it is used for library funding (01000), and would be willing to accept taxes at the current rate (00000), but would not support both tax hikes (11000).

Finally, as a third example, again suppose that Agent 1 is in state 10000, but Agent 2 is in state 11111. As a result of this communication, Agent 1 could not move to 01000, but could move to 11110 or 11111. However, the chance of these moves is \(\mu ^{j}(1-\mu )^{k}\), where j is the number of features that must change and and k is the number of differences that must not change. For \(mu=.3\), the chance of Agent 1 moving to state 11110 on the basis of this interaction is .0189.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Mueller, S.T., Tan, YY.S. Cognitive perspectives on opinion dynamics: the role of knowledge in consensus formation, opinion divergence, and group polarization. J Comput Soc Sc 1, 15–48 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s42001-017-0004-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s42001-017-0004-7

Keywords

Navigation