Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Remanufacturing Models Under Technology Licensing with Consideration of Environmental Issues

  • Original Research Paper
  • Published:
Process Integration and Optimization for Sustainability Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Recently, the environmental and economic benefits of remanufacturing result in increasing interest of this concept. Due to supreme importance of this issue, in this paper, a closed-loop supply chain (CLSC) including a manufacturer, a distributor, and third-party logistics provider is considered. Three multi-level leader-follower Stackelberg game models are presented in order to investigate whether a manufacturer in addition to manufacturing new products should do remanufacturing or sets a fee for technology licensing of distributors and cooperate with them in remanufacturing. Furthermore, we conduct a sensitivity analysis to show how government can mitigate the bad economic, environmental, and social impacts of remanufacturing by setting an emissions tax price and evaluation of impacts of changing remanufacturing parameters on the profit of supply chain members on the three proposed models.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Abbey JD, Blackburn JD, Guide VDR (2015) Optimal pricing for new and remanufactured products. J Oper Manag 36:130–146

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bard JF, Moore JT (1992) An algorithm for the discrete bilevel programming problem. Naval Research Logistics (NRL) 39(3):419–435

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Chang X, Xia H, Zhu H, Fan T, Zhao H (2015) Production decisions in a hybrid manufacturing–remanufacturing system with carbon cap and trade mechanism. Int J Prod Econ 162:160–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang X, Li Y, Zhao Y, Liu W, Wu J (2017) Effects of carbon permits allocation methods on remanufacturing production decisions. J Clean Prod 152:281–294

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen J-M, Chang C-I (2013) Dynamic pricing for new and remanufactured products in a closed-loop supply chain. Int J Prod Econ 146(1):153–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen W, Kucukyazici B, Verter V, Saenz MJ (2015) Supply chain design for unlocking the value of remanufacturing under uncertainty. Eur J Oper Res 247(3):804–819

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Choi T, Li Y, Xu L (2013) Channel leadership, performance and coordination in closed loop supply chains. Intern J Prod Econ 146(1):371–380

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chuang C-H, Wang CX, Zhao Y (2014) Closed-loop supply chain models for a high-tech product under alternative reverse channel and collection cost structures. Int J Prod Econ 156:108–123

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cunha JO, Konstantaras I, Melo RA, Sifaleras A (2017) On multi-item economic lot-sizing with remanufacturing and uncapacitated production. Appl Math Model 50:772–780

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • DeNegre ST, Ralphs TK (2009) A branch-and-cut algorithm for integer bilevel linear programs. In: Operations research and cyber-infrastructure. Springer, Berlin, pp 65–78

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Edmunds TA, Bard JF (1992) An algorithm for the mixed-integer nonlinear bilevel programming problem. Ann Oper Res 34(1):149–162

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Gan S-S, Pujawan IN, Widodo B (2017) Pricing decision for new and remanufactured product in a closed-loop supply chain with separate sales-channel. Int J Prod Econ 190:120–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghavamifar A, Makui A, Taleizadeh AA (2018) Designing a resilient competitive supply chain network under disruption risks: a real-world application. Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review 115:87–109

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hazen BT, Overstreet RE, Jones-Farmer LA, Field HS (2012) The role of ambiguity tolerance in consumer perception of remanufactured products. Int J Prod Econ 135(2):781–790

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hong X, Zhang H, Zhong Q, Liu L (2016) Optimal decisions of a hybrid manufacturing-remanufacturing system within a closed-loop supply chain. European Journal of Industrial Engineering 10(1):21–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang Y, Wang Z (2017) Closed-loop supply chain models with product take-back and hybrid remanufacturing under technology licensing. J Clean Prod 142:3917–3927

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang M, Song M, Lee LH, Ching WK (2013) Analysis for strategy of closed-loop supply chain with dual recycling channel. Int J Prod Econ 144(2):510–520

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ijomah WL, Childe S, McMahon C (2004) Remanufacturing: a key strategy for sustainable development. 3rd International Conference on Design and Manufacture for Sustainable Development

  • Jena SK, Sarmah SP (2014) Price competition and co-operation in a duopoly closed-loop supply chain. Int J Prod Econ 156:346–360

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kazemian I, Rabbani M, Farrokhi-Asl H (2018) A way to optimally solve a green time-dependent vehicle routing problem with time windows. Comput Appl Math 37(3):2766–2783

  • Kwak M, Kim H (2017) Green profit maximization through integrated pricing and production planning for a line of new and remanufactured products. J Clean Prod 142:3454–3470

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee C-M, Woo W-S, Roh Y-H (2017) Remanufacturing: trends and issues. International Journal of Precision Engineering and Manufacturing-Green Technology 4(1):113–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu L, Wang Z, Xu L, Hong X, Govindan K (2017) Collection effort and reverse channel choices in a closed-loop supply chain. J Clean Prod 144:492–500

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maleki L, Pasandideh SHR, Niaki STA, Cárdenas-Barrón LE (2017) Determining the prices of remanufactured products, capacity of internal workstations and the contracting strategy within queuing framework. Appl Soft Comput 54:313–321

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsumoto M, Yang S, Martinsen K, Kainuma Y (2016) Trends and research challenges in remanufacturing. International Journal of Precision Engineering and Manufacturing-Green Technology 3(1):129–142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miao Z, Mao H, Fu K, Wang Y (2018) Remanufacturing with trade-ins under carbon regulations. Comput Oper Res 89:253–268

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Moore JT, Bard JF (1990) The mixed integer linear bilevel programming problem. Oper Res 38(5):911–921

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Oraiopoulos N, Ferguson ME, Toktay LB (2012) Relicensing as a secondary market strategy. Manag Sci 58(5):1022–1037

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Örsdemir A, Kemahlıoğlu-Ziya E, Parlaktürk AK (2014) Competitive quality choice and remanufacturing. Prod Oper Manag 23(1):48–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson AB, Tuli KR, Kohli AK (2015) Does brand licensing increase a licensor’s shareholder value? Manag Sci 61(6):1436–1455

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Safaei N, Saidi-Mehrabad M, Babakhani M (2007) Designing cellular manufacturing systems under dynamic and uncertain conditions. J Intell Manuf 18(3):383–399

  • Saharidis GK, Ierapetritou MG (2009) Resolution method for mixed integer bi-level linear problems based on decomposition technique. J Glob Optim 44(1):29–51

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Savaskan RC, Van Wassenhove LN (2006) Reverse channel design: the case of competing retailers. Manag Sci 52(1):1–14

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Savaskan RC, Bhattacharya S, Van Wassenhove LN (2004) Closed-loop supply chain models with product remanufacturing. Manag Sci 50(2):239–252

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Savva N, Taneri N (2015) The role of equity, royalty, and fixed fees in technology licensing to university spin-offs. Manag Sci 61(6):1323–1343

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shakourloo A, Kazemi A, Javad MOM (2016) A new model for more effective supplier selection and remanufacturing process in a closed-loop supply chain. Appl Math Model 40(23):9914–9931

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Shen C, Xiong Z, Peng Z (2013) Decision and coordination research for remanufacturing closed-loop supply chain under patent protection and government subsidies. [J] Journal of Industrial Engineering and Engineering Management 3:019

    Google Scholar 

  • Shi J, Zhang G, Sha J (2011) Optimal production planning for a multi-product closed loop system with uncertain demand and return. Computers and Operation Research 38(3):641–650

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Shu T, Liao H, Chen S, Wang S, Lai KK, Gan L (2016) Analysing remanufacturing decisions of supply chain members in uncertainty of consumer preferences. Appl Econ 48(34):3208–3227

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Souza GC (2013) Closed-loop supply chains: a critical review, and future research. Decis Sci 44(1):7–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Subramanian R, Subramanyam R (2012) Key factors in the market for remanufactured products. Manuf Serv Oper Manag Publ 14(2):315–326

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tao ZG, Guang ZY, Hao S, Song HJ (2015) Multi-period closed-loop supply chain network equilibrium with carbon emission constraints. Resour Conserv Recycl 104:354–365

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thierry M, Salomon M, Van Nunen J, Van Wassenhove L (1995) Strategic issues in product recovery management. Calif Manag Rev 37(2):114–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang Y, Chen W (2017) Effects of emissions constraint on manufacturing/remanufacturing decisions considering capital constraint and financing. Atmospheric Pollution Research 8(3):455–464

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang Y, Chen W, Liu B (2017) Manufacturing/remanufacturing decisions for a capital-constrained manufacturer considering carbon emission cap and trade. J Clean Prod 140:1118–1128

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wei J, Zhao J, Li Y (2015) Price and warranty period decisions for complementary products with horizontal firms’ cooperation/noncooperation strategies. J Clean Prod 105:86–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu C-H (2012) Product-design and pricing strategies with remanufacturing. Eur J Oper Res 222(2):204–215

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Xiong Y, Zhao Q, Zhou Y (2016) Manufacturer-remanufacturing vs supplier-remanufacturing in a closed-loop supply chain. Int J Prod Econ 176:21–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang L, Wang G, Ke C (2018) Remanufacturing and promotion in dual-channel supply chains under cap-and-trade regulation. J Clean Prod 204:939–957

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yenipazarli A (2016) Managing new and remanufactured products to mitigate environmental damage under emissions regulation. Eur J Oper Res 249(1):117–130

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Yi P, Huang M, Guo L, Shi T (2016a) A retailer oriented closed-loop supply chain network design for end of life construction machinery remanufacturing. J Clean Prod 137:1393–1405

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yi P, Huang M, Guo L, Shi T (2016b) Dual recycling channel decision in retailer oriented closed-loop supply chain for construction machinery remanufacturing. J Clean Prod 137:1393–1405

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhao D, Chen H, Hong X, Liu J (2014) Technology licensing contracts with network effects. Int J Prod Econ 158:136–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhao S, Zhu Q, Cui L (2018) A decision-making model for remanufacturers: considering both consumers’ environmental preference and the government subsidy policy. Resour Conserv Recycl 128:176–186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zou Z-B, Wang J-J, Deng G-S, Chen H (2016) Third-party remanufacturing mode selection: outsourcing or authorization? Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review 87:1–19

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Masoud Rabbani.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1.The proofs of the propositions of the Model 1

Proof of the proposition 1.

$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}_2^{d1}}{\partial {P}_r^2}=\alpha -2\beta {P}_r^2+\beta {P}_w^2 $$
(47)
$$ \frac{\partial^2{\pi}_2^{d1}}{\partial {P}_r^{2^2}}=-2\beta $$
(48)

As −2β < 0, the distributor profit function in the second period is concave in \( {P}_r^2. \)

Proof of the proposition 2. As the second period profit function of the distributor is concave in \( {P}_r^2 \), we can obtain retail prices for the new and remanufactured products in the second period by setting the first-order derivatives to zero.

$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}_2^{d1}}{\partial {P}_r^2}=\alpha -2\beta {P}_r^2+\beta {P}_w^2=0 $$
(49)

Proof of the proposition 3.

$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}^{d1}}{\partial {P}_r^1}=\alpha -2\beta {P}_r^1+\beta {P}_w^1 $$
(50)
$$ \frac{\partial^2{\pi}^{d1}}{\partial {P}_r^{1^2}}=-2\beta $$
(51)

As −2β < 0, the distributor profit function in the two-period is concave in \( {P}_r^1. \).

Proof of the proposition 4.

As the two-period profit function of the distributor is concave in \( {P}_r^1 \), we can obtain retail prices for the new products in the first period by setting the first-order derivatives to zero.

$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}^{d1}}{\partial {P}_r^1}=\alpha -2\beta {P}_r^1+\beta {P}_w^1=0 $$
(52)

Proof of the proposition 5.

$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}_2^{m1}}{\partial {P}_w^2}=\frac{\alpha -2\beta {P}_w^2}{2}+\frac{\beta \left(\delta +{C}_n\right)}{2} $$
(53)
$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}_2^{m1}}{\partial {C}_c}=\left(\alpha -\beta {P}_r^1\right)\left[\frac{\theta \left(-{C}_r+{C}_n+\delta \left(1-\lambda \right)\right)-{C}_c}{2\sqrt{d{C}_c}}-\sqrt{\frac{C_c}{d}}\right] $$
(54)
$$ {H}_m^1=\left[\begin{array}{cc}{\partial}^2{\pi}_2^{m1}/\partial {P}_w^{2^2}& {\partial}^2{\pi}_2^{m1}/\partial {P}_w^2\partial {C}_c\\ {}{\partial}^2{\pi}_2^{m1}/\partial {C}_c\partial {P}_w^2& {\partial}^2{\pi}_2^{m1}/\partial {C}_c^2\end{array}\right]=\left[\begin{array}{cc}-\beta & 0\\ {}0& -\left(\alpha -\beta {P}_r^1\right)\left[\frac{3{C}_c+\theta \left({C}_n+\delta -{C}_r-\lambda \delta \right)}{4{C}_c\sqrt{d{C}_c}}\right]\end{array}\right] $$
(55)

As \( -\beta <0\ \mathrm{and}\ \left|{H}_m^1\right|>0 \), so the manufacturer’s profit function in the second period \( {\pi}_2^{m1} \) is jointly concave in \( {P}_w^2 \) and Cc.

Proof of the proposition 6.

As the second period profit function of the manufacturer is concave in Cc and \( {P}_w^2 \), we can obtain the optimal acquisition price of a unit of a used product which is returned from consumers and wholesale prices for new and remanufactured products in the second period by setting the first-order derivatives to zero.

$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}_2^{m1}}{\partial {C}_c}=\frac{\theta \left({C}_n+\delta -{C}_r-\lambda \delta \right)-{C}_c-2d{C}_c}{2d\sqrt{\frac{C_c}{d}}}=0 $$
(56)
$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}_2^{m1}}{\partial {P}_w^2}=\frac{\alpha -2\beta {P}_w^2}{2}+\frac{\beta \left(\delta +{C}_n\right)}{2}=0 $$
(57)

Proof of the proposition 7.

$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}^{m1}}{\partial {P}_w^1}=\frac{\alpha -2\beta {P}_w^1+\beta \left({C}_n+\delta \right)}{2} $$
(58)
$$ \frac{\partial^2{\pi}^{m1}}{\partial {P}_w^{1^2}}=-\beta $$
(59)

As −β < 0, the manufacturer profit function in the two-period is concave in \( {P}_w^1. \).

Proof of the proposition 8.

As the two-period profit function of the manufacturer is concave in \( {P}_w^1 \), we can obtain wholesale prices for the new products in the first period by setting the first-order derivatives to zero.

$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}^{m1}}{\partial {P}_w^1}=\frac{\alpha -2\beta {P}_w^1+\beta \left({C}_n+\delta \right)}{2}=0 $$
(60)

Appendix 2. The proofs of the propositions of the Model 2

Proof of the proposition 9.

$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}_2^{d2}}{\partial {P}_r^2}=\alpha -2\beta {P}_r^2+\beta {P}_w^2 $$
(61)
$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}_2^{d2}}{\partial {C}_c}=\left(\alpha -\beta {P}_r^1\right)\left(\frac{C_d\theta }{2\sqrt{C_cd}}-1.5\sqrt{\frac{C_c}{d}}\right) $$
(62)
$$ {H}_d^2=\left[\begin{array}{cc}{\partial}^2{\pi}_2^{d2}/\partial {P}_r^{2^2}& {\partial}^2{\pi}_2^{d2}/\partial {P}_r^2\partial {C}_c\\ {}{\partial}^2{\pi}_2^{d2}/\partial {C}_c\partial {P}_r^2& {\partial}^2{\pi}_2^{d2}/\partial {C}_c^2\end{array}\right]=\left[\begin{array}{cc}-2\beta & 0\\ {}0& -\frac{\alpha -\beta {P}_r^1}{\sqrt{C_cd}}\end{array}\right] $$
(63)

As −2β < 0 and\( \left|{H}_d^2\right|>0, \) so the distributor’s profit function in the second period \( {\pi}_2^{m2} \) is jointly concave in \( {P}_r^2 \) and Cc.

Proof of the proposition 10. As the second period profit function of the distributor is concave in Cc and \( {P}_r^2 \), we can obtain the optimal acquisition price of a unit of a used product which is returned from consumers and retail prices for new and remanufactured products in the second period by setting the first-order derivatives to zero.

$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}_2^{d2}}{\partial {P}_r^2}=\alpha -2\beta {P}_r^2+\beta {P}_w^2=0 $$
(64)
$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}_2^{d2}}{\partial {C}_c}=\left({C}_d\theta -{C}_c\right)\sqrt{\frac{C_c}{d}}=0 $$
(65)

Proof of the proposition 11.

$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}^{d2}}{\partial {P}_r^1}=\alpha -2\beta {P}_r^1+\beta {P}_w^1-\frac{2{C}_d\theta \beta}{3}\sqrt{\frac{C_d\theta }{3d}} $$
(66)
$$ \frac{\partial^2{\pi}^{d2}}{\partial {P}_r^{1^2}}=-2\beta $$
(67)

As −2β < 0, the distributor profit function in the two periods is concave in \( {P}_r^1. \).

Proof of the proposition 12. As the two-period profit function of the distributor is concave in \( {P}_r^1 \), we can obtain the optimal retail prices for new in the first period by setting the first-order derivatives to zero.

$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}^{d2}}{\partial {P}_r^1}=\alpha -2\beta {P}_r^1+\beta {P}_w^1-\frac{2{C}_d\theta \beta}{3}\sqrt{\frac{C_d\theta }{3d}}=0 $$
(68)

Proof of the proposition 13.

$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}_2^{m2}}{\partial {P}_w^2}=\frac{\alpha -2\beta {P}_w^2+\beta \left({C}_n+\delta \right)}{2} $$
(69)
$$ \frac{\partial^2{\pi}_2^{m2}}{\partial {P}_w^{2^2}}=-\beta $$
(70)

As −β < 0, the manufacturer profit function in the second period is concave in \( {P}_w^2. \)

Proof of the proposition 14. As the second period profit function of the manufacturer is concave in \( {P}_w^2 \), we can obtain the optimal wholesale prices for the new and remanufactured products in the second period by setting the first-order derivatives to zero.

$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}_2^{m2}}{\partial {P}_w^2}=\frac{\alpha -2\beta {P}_w^2+\beta \left({C}_n+\delta \right)}{2}=0 $$
(71)

Proof of the proposition 15.

$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}_2^{m2}}{\partial {P}_w^1}=\frac{\alpha -2\beta {P}_w^1+\beta \left({C}_n+\delta \right)}{2}-\beta \frac{\theta }{2}\sqrt{\frac{C_d\theta }{3d}}\left({C}_n+\delta \left(1-\lambda \right)-{C}_r-{C}_d\right) $$
(72)
$$ \frac{\partial^2{\pi}_2^{m2}}{\partial {P}_w^{1^2}}=-\beta $$
(73)

As −β < 0, the manufacturer profit function in the two-period is concave in \( {P}_w^1. \).

Proof of the proposition 16. As the two-period profit function of the manufacturer is concave in \( {P}_w^1 \), we can obtain the optimal wholesale prices for the new products in the first period by setting the first-order derivatives to zero.

$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}_2^{m2}}{\partial {P}_w^1}=\frac{\alpha -2\beta {P}_w^1+\beta \left({C}_n+\delta \right)}{2}-\beta \frac{\theta }{2}\sqrt{\frac{C_d\theta }{3d}}\left({C}_n+\delta \left(1-\lambda \right)-{C}_r-{C}_d\right)=0 $$
(74)

Appendix 3. The proofs of the propositions of Model 3

Proof of the proposition 17.

$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}_2^{t3}}{\partial {C}_c}=\frac{\left({C}_t-{C}_c\right)\left(\alpha -\beta {P}_r^1\right)\theta }{2d\sqrt{\frac{C_c}{d}}}-\sqrt{\frac{C_c}{d}}\left(\alpha -\beta {P}_r^1\right)\theta $$
(75)
$$ \frac{\partial^2{\pi}_2^{t3}}{\partial {C}_c^2}=-\frac{\theta \left(\alpha -\beta {P}_r^1\right)\sqrt{C_cd}+\frac{d\theta \left(\alpha -\beta {P}_r^1\right)\left({C}_c-{C}_t\right)}{2\sqrt{C_cd}}}{2{C}_c} $$
(76)

Since \( {\partial}^2{\pi}_2^{t3}/\partial {C}_c^2<0 \), so the third party’s profit function in the second period \( {\pi}_2^{t2} \) is concave in Cc.

Proof of the proposition 18. As the second period profit function of the third party is concave in Cc , we can obtain the optimal acquisition price of a unit of a used product which is returned from consumers in the second period by setting the first-order derivatives to zero.

$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}_2^{t3}}{\partial {C}_c}=\frac{\left({C}_t-{C}_c\right)\left(\alpha -\beta {P}_r^1\right)\theta }{2d\sqrt{\frac{C_c}{d}}}-\sqrt{\frac{C_c}{d}}\left(\alpha -\beta {P}_r^1\right)\theta =0 $$
(77)

Proof of the proposition 19 .

$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}_2^{d3}}{\partial {P}_r^2}=\alpha -2\beta {P}_r^2+\beta {P}_w^2 $$
(78)
$$ \frac{\partial^2{\pi}_2^{d3}}{\partial {P}_r^{2^2}}=-2\beta $$
(79)

Since −2β < 0, so the distributor’s profit function in the second period \( {\pi}_3^{d2} \) is concave in \( {P}_r^2 \).

Proof of the proposition 20. As the second period profit function of the distributor is concave in \( {P}_r^2 \), we can obtain the optimal retail prices for new and remanufactured products in the second period by setting the first-order derivatives to zero.

$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}_2^{d3}}{\partial {P}_r^2}=\alpha -2\beta {P}_r^2+\beta {P}_w^2=0 $$
(80)

Proof of the proposition 21.

$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}^{d3}}{\partial {P}_r^1}=\alpha -2\beta {P}_r^1+{P}_w^1\beta -\left[\left({P}_w^2-{C}_r-{C}_t\right)\omega \theta - l\omega \theta \right]\beta \sqrt{\frac{C_t}{3d}} $$
(81)
$$ \frac{\partial^2{\pi}^{d3}}{\partial {P}_r^{1^2}}=-2\beta $$
(82)

As −2β < 0, the distributor profit function in the two-period is concave in \( {P}_r^1. \).

Proof of the proposition 22. As the two-period profit function of the distributor is concave in \( {P}_r^1 \), we can obtain the optimal retail prices for new in the first period by setting the first-order derivatives to zero.

$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}^{d3}}{\partial {P}_r^1}=\alpha -2\beta {P}_r^1+{P}_w^1\beta -\left[\left({P}_w^2-{C}_r-{C}_t\right)\omega \theta - l\omega \theta \right]\beta \sqrt{\frac{C_t}{3d}}=0 $$
(83)

Proof of the proposition 23.

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}\frac{\partial {\pi}_2^{m3}}{\partial {P}_w^2}=\frac{\alpha -2\beta {P}_w^2+\beta \left({C}_n+\delta \right)}{2}\\ {}\kern1.92em +\frac{\theta \omega}{2}\sqrt{\frac{C_t}{3d}}\left\{\beta \theta \sqrt{\frac{C_t}{3d}}\left[\left(2\omega -1\right)\left({C}_r+{C}_t+\lambda \delta \right)+{C}_n+\delta -2\omega {P}_w^2\right]-\alpha +\beta {P}_w^1\right\}\end{array}} $$
(84)
$$ \frac{\partial^2{\pi}_2^{m3}}{\partial {P}_w^{2^2}}=-\beta {P}_w^2-{\theta}^2{\omega}^2\beta \frac{C_t}{3d} $$
(85)

As −β − θ2ω2βCt/3d < 0 , the manufacturer profit function in the second period is concave in \( {P}_w^2. \)

Proof of the proposition 24. As the second period profit function of the manufacturer is concave in \( {P}_w^2 \), we can obtain the optimal wholesale prices for the new and remanufactured products in the second period by setting the first-order derivatives to zero.

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}\frac{\partial {\pi}_2^{m3}}{\partial {P}_w^2}=\frac{\alpha -2\beta {P}_w^2+\beta \left({C}_n+\delta \right)}{2}\\ {}\kern1.92em +\frac{\theta \omega}{2}\sqrt{\frac{C_t}{3d}}\left\{\beta \theta \sqrt{\frac{C_t}{3d}}\left[\left(2\omega -1\right)\left({C}_r+{C}_t+\lambda \delta \right)+{C}_n+\delta -2\omega {P}_w^2\right]-\alpha +\beta {P}_w^1\right\}=0\end{array}} $$
(86)

Proof of the proposition 25.

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}\frac{\partial {\pi}^{m2}}{\partial {P}_w^1}=\frac{\alpha -2\beta {P}_w^1+\beta \left({C}_n+\delta \right)}{2}+B\frac{\alpha -\beta \left(2A+2B{P}_w^1\right)+\beta \left({C}_n+\delta \right)}{2}\\ {}+\beta \frac{\theta }{2}\left[\omega \theta B\frac{\theta {C}_t}{3d}-\sqrt{\frac{C_t}{3d}}\right]\left[{C}_n+\delta -{C}_r-{C}_t-\lambda \delta -\omega \left(A+B{P}_w^1-{C}_r-{C}_t-\lambda \delta +l\right)\right]\\ {}-\omega B\left[\frac{\theta }{2}\sqrt{\frac{C_t}{3d}}\left(\alpha -\beta {P}_w^1+\beta \omega \theta \left[A+B{P}_w^1-{C}_r-{C}_t-l\right]\sqrt{\frac{C_t}{3d}}\right)\right]\end{array}} $$
(87)
$$ \frac{\partial^2{\pi}^{m2}}{\partial {P}_w^{1^2}}=-\beta -\beta B{}^2-\omega \theta B\beta \sqrt{\frac{C_t}{3d}}\left[\omega {\theta}^2B\sqrt{\frac{C_t}{3d}}-1\right] $$
(88)

If \( \omega {\theta}^2B\sqrt{C_t/3d}\ge 1, \) then \( {\partial}^2{\pi}^{m2}/\partial {P}_w^{1^2}<0 \); otherwise, if \( \omega {\theta}^2B\sqrt{C_t/3d}<1, \) then \( -1\le \omega {\theta}^2B\sqrt{C_t/3d}-1<0 \) and in the pessimistic case if \( \omega {\theta}^2B\sqrt{C_t/3d}-1=-1, \) then as \( 1+{B}^2>\omega {\theta}^2B\sqrt{C_t/3d},{\partial}^2{\pi}^{m2}/\partial {P}_w^{1^2}<0. \) So, the manufacturer profit function in the two periods is concave in \( {P}_w^1 \).

Proof of the proposition 26. As the two-period profit function of the manufacturer is concave in \( \kern0.5em {P}_w^1 \), we can obtain the optimal wholesale prices for the new products in the first period by setting the first-order derivatives to zero.

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}\frac{\partial {\pi}^{m2}}{\partial {P}_w^1}=\frac{\alpha -2\beta {P}_w^1+\beta \left({C}_n+\delta \right)}{2}+B\frac{\alpha -2\beta \left(A+B{P}_w^1\right)+\beta \left({C}_n+\delta \right)}{2}\\ {}+\beta \frac{\theta }{2}\left[\omega \theta B\frac{\theta {C}_t}{3d}-\sqrt{\frac{C_t}{3d}}\right]\left[{C}_n+\delta -{C}_r-{C}_t-\lambda \delta -\omega \left(A+B{P}_w^1-{C}_r-{C}_t-\lambda \delta +l\right)\right]\\ {}-\omega B\left[\frac{\theta }{2}\sqrt{\frac{C_t}{3d}}\left(\alpha -\beta {P}_w^1+\beta \omega \theta \sqrt{\frac{C_t}{3d}}\left[A+B{P}_w^1-{C}_r-{C}_t-l\right]\right)\right]=0\end{array}} $$

The results of the sensitivity analysis

The results of the sensitivity analysis by changing the tax rate are provided in Tables 4, 5, and 6.

Table 4 displays the effect of changing the tax rate on the profit of the manufacturer and distributor in each model and period.

Table 4 Effect of changing the tax rate on the profit of the manufacturer and distributor
Table 5 Effect of changing the tax rate on unit retail price
Table 6 Effect of changing the tax rate on the demand
Table 7 Effect of changing the licensing fee on the profit of the manufacturer and distributor
Table 8 Effect of changing ω on the profit of the manufacturer and distributor

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Rabbani, M., Ahmadzadeh, K. & Farrokhi-Asl, H. Remanufacturing Models Under Technology Licensing with Consideration of Environmental Issues. Process Integr Optim Sustain 3, 383–401 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s41660-019-00085-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s41660-019-00085-8

Keywords

Navigation