Abstract
We investigate the performance of a voting procedure in which voters cast multiple votes, with some votes positive and some negative. The procedure is a variant of the “D21” method proposed by Janeček (2016). The setting is the 2018 Czech Republic presidential election. Evidence is provided through a survey of secondary school students asked to cast ballots in both single- and multi-vote election experiments. Using the survey data, we estimate a spatial voting model to uncover ideological positions of candidates and respondents. Results suggest that the multi-vote procedure may limit the success of extreme candidates in elections.
This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.




Notes
The voting procedure applied in this study did not impose the D21 requirement of the 2:1 ratio of positive to negative votes.
Analysis of the second wave survey data produced results that were qualitatively similar to those obtained with the first. Results of that analysis are provided in an online appendix.
The original sample included 304 students, but three were eliminated because their ballots reported either zero votes or more than three votes, violating the election rules.
Poole and Rosenthal recover spatial locations of the choices voted upon as well as the locations of the legislators. In our model, we similarly recover the locations of candidates (the choices) and those of the voters. Logit and probit models assume different distributions for the model error terms, but this is not normally a matter of importance.
In the Poole-Rosenthal applications, there are only two choice options available to legislators. Vote probabilities depend on the distances of the candidate from each of the two options.
This does not presuppose that these candidates were extreme, as the range for positions of other candidates is not restricted. For example, other candidates could have had estimated positions near 1000 or − 1000.
The 2018 Czech election was seen as a battle “between authoritarianism and liberal democracy, between east and west,” where Zeman, a pro-Russian politician represented authoritarianism and east, while Drahos, a pro-EU academic with no prior political experience was a pro-west liberal (Cameron 2018).
Fully accounting for all of these issues would be very difficult. There are no off-the-shelf econometric models that are strictly appropriate.
As we have noted, our functional form imposes a lower bound on voter utilities. A consequence is that when distances between candidates and voters become very large, additional changes in distance have negligible marginal impacts on utility and extreme voter positions are not well-identified.
References
Alcantud, J., & Laruelle, A. (2014). Disapproval voting: A characterization. Social Choice and Welfare, 43(1), 1–10.
Alós-Ferrer, C., & Granic, D. (2012). Two field experiments on approval voting in Germany. Social Choice and Welfare, 39(1), 171–205.
Baharad, E., & Nitzan, S. (2016). Is majority consistency possible? Social Choice and Welfare, 46(2), 287–299.
Balinski, M., & Laraki, R. (2007). Election by majority judgement: experimental evidence. Cahiers du Laboratoire d’Econométrie de l’Ecole Polytechnique, 28, 2007.
Baujard, A., & Igersheim, H. (2010). Framed field experiments on approval voting: lessons from the 2012 and 2017 French Presidential Elections. In J. Laslier & M. Sanver (Eds.), Handbook on Approval Voting (pp. 357–395). Springer.
Baujard, A., Igersheim, H., Lebon, I., Gavrel, F., & Laslier, J. F. (2014). Who’s favored by evaluative voting? An experiment conducted during the 2012 French presidential election. Electoral Studies, 34, 131–145.
Baujard, A., Igersheim, H., & Senne, T. (2011). The political supply in the 2007 French Presidential Elections: An analysis based on experimental data. Annals of Economics and Statistics 101/102, Social Choice and Voting, 149–186.
Boehm, G.A.W. (1976). One fervent vote against Wintergreen. Mimeograph. Cahiers du Laboratoire d’Econométrie de l’Ecole Polytechnique, no. 28, 2007.
Cameron, B. (January 21, 2018). Milos Zeman vote settles Czech presidency—or does it? BBC News, Retrieved from https://www.bbc.com/news/world-europe-42848835, 29 Nov 2018.
Janecek, K. (August 29, 2016). Democracy 2.1, 1–12, 5. Retrieved from https://uploads-ssl.webflow.com/5a61da42ae3f8f00019b46bd/5a893542d9716c0001a4a80d_d21.pdf.
Laslier, J., & Van der Straeten, K. (2008). A live experiment on approval voting. Experimental Economics, 11(1), 97–105.
Mueller, D. (2003). Public choice III. Cambridge University Press.
Nurmi, H. (1983). Voting procedures: a summary analysis. British Journal of Political Science, 13(2), 181–208.
Poole, K. T., & Rosenthal, H. R. (1985). A spatial model for legislative roll call analysis. American Journal of Political Science, 29(2), 357–384.
Yilmaz, M. (1999). Can we improve upon approval voting? European Journal of Political Economy, 15(1), 89–100.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Additional information
Publisher's Note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Tanya Gibbs, former Chief Research Officer, Institute H21, Prague, Czech Republic
Supplementary Information
Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Gibbs, T., Chappell, Jr., H.W. Elections with Multiple Positive and Negative Votes. Homo Oecon 38, 37–47 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s41412-021-00109-0
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s41412-021-00109-0