Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Intergroup Revenge: A Laboratory Experiment

  • Research Paper
  • Published:
Homo Oeconomicus Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Several everyday examples imply that humans reciprocate not only towards direct perpetrators, but also to entire groups, thereby potentially affecting innocent bystanders. We test the hypothesis that people are predisposed to reciprocate against groups. In a laboratory experiment, subjects who were helped or harmed by another player’s action reacted by helping or harming another member of that player’s group. This group reciprocity was only observed when one group was seen as unfairly advantaged. Thus, activation of group reciprocity may be a causal mechanism that links perceived injustice to intergroup conflict. We discuss the relevance of group reciprocity to political and economic phenomena including violence, discrimination and team competition.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. It was forbidden to communicate personal information. All subjects followed these instructions.

  2. 100 ECU per subject were described as an endowment for the second part of the experiment. To ensure that each subject had at least 100 ECU, minimum group earnings of 400 ECU were implemented. This endowment was purely a framing manipulation to increase subjects’ sense that they had “earned” their ECU.

  3. The reason for the imbalance between the number of sessions in each treatment is as follows: we wished to examine individual-level correlates of group reciprocity, so we ran extra sessions using the random bonus treatment which turned out to induce group reciprocity. Note that our results are significant when aggregating across all types of sessions.

  4. By “harm”, we simply mean “reduce the other’s earnings”. We cannot be sure whether our subjects perceived taking from the common fund as harmful or simply as not helpful, since this depends on what they perceived to be the default or baseline action.

  5. Subjects might become more generous to other members of their own group in the face of an external threat (e.g. Sherif et al. 1961). To avoid this potential confound, we ensured that P2 was never from the subject’s own group.

  6. In third party repetitions, we also varied whether the feedback player P1 was playing against someone from the subject’s own group, or someone from a different, neutral group. This allows us to examine whether subjects react more strongly when P1’s action affects a member of the subject’s own group. As overall results from third party treatments were null, we do not report further on this here.

  7. Two of our sessions used only the first party treatment.

  8. The online appendix shows participants’ descriptive statistics, including demographics.

  9. A derivation is in the online appendix.

  10. These include removing the fixed effects; using session- rather than individual-clustered standard errors; adding controls for the history of play; and running Tobit regressions.

  11. This is within random bonus sessions only. Results are similar in winner bonus sessions. Controlling for fairness perceptions reduces, but does not eliminate, the difference between sessions.

  12. In fact, there were no significant correlations within groups.

  13. If we do not multiply impute Expectations, we lose all repetitions other than 2 and 7. Results on repetitions 2 and 7 alone are insignificant whether or not Expectations are included.

  14. Expectations was imputed from the following variables: first round amount taken by participant F, first and second round amounts taken by the subject and his/her own round 1 and round 2 partners, lags of these amounts from the previous repetition; amount the subject last saw taken by a participant from the same colour group as the current partner; a quadratic in repetition (from 1 to 8), and treatment dummies.

  15. To gather more information, these sessions only included first party treatments, with two repetitions of each color treatment.

  16. A pooled linear regression without fixed effects also gives a significant result at 5%. A Tobit model and a linear regression model including controls for the history of play did not reach significance, although the coefficients had the same signs.

References

  • Abbink, K., and Herrmann, B. (2009). Pointless Vedettas. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1468452. Accessed 10 July 2017.

  • Alm, J., & Torgler, B. (2006). Cultural differences and tax morale in the United States and Europe. Journal of Economic Psychology, 27, 224–246.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1972). Some mathematical models of race discrimination in the labor market. In H. P. Anthony (Ed.), Racial discrimination in economic life (pp. 187–203). Lexington (Mass.): Lexington Books.

  • Aureli, F., Cozzolino, R., Cordischi, C., & Scucchi, S. (1992). Kin-Oriented Redirection among Japanese Macaques: An expression of a revenge system? Animal Behaviour, 44(2), 283–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ball, S., & Eckel, C. C. (1998). The Economic Value of Status. Journal of Socio-Economics, 27(4), 495–514.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bauerlein, M. (2001). Negrophobia: A race riot in Atlanta, 1906. New York: Encounter Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernhard, H., Fischbacher, U., & Fehr, E. (2006). Parochial altruism in humans. Nature, 442(7105), 912–915.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bornhorst, F., Ichino, A., Kirchkamp, O., Schlag, K., & Winter, E. (2010). Similarities and differences when building trust: The role of cultures. Experimental Economics, 13(3), 260–283.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bornstein, G. (1992). The free-rider problem in intergroup conflicts over step-level and continuous public goods. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 62(4), 597.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bornstein, G. (2003). Intergroup conflict: individual, Group, And Collective Interests. Personality and Social Psychology Review, 7(2), 129–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brass, P. R. (1997). Theft of an idol: Text and context in the representation of collective violence. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brewer, M. B. (1999). The psychology of prejudice: Ingroup love and outgroup hate? Journal of Social Issues, 55(3), 429–444.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cederman, L. E., Weidmann, N. B., & Gleditsch, K. S. (2011). Horizontal inequalities and Ethno-Nationalist Civil War: A global comparison. American Political Science Review, 105(3), 478–495.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chagnon, N. A. (1988). Life histories, blood revenge, and warfare in a tribal population. Science, 239(4843), 985–992.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, R., & Chen, Y. (2011). The potential of social identity for equilibrium selection. American Economic Review, 101(6), 2562–2589.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Y., & Li, S. X. (2009). Group identity and social preferences. American Economic Review, 99(1), 431–457.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cherry, T. L., Frykblom, P., & Shogren, J. F. (2002). Hardnose the dictator. American Economic Review, 92(4), 1218–1221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Currarini, S., & Mengel, F. (2012). Identity, homophily and in-group bias. FEEM Working Paper 37.

  • de Cremer, D., & van Vugt, M. (1999). Leadership in social dilemmas: The effects of group identification on collective actions to provide public goods. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 76(4), 587–599.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dufwenberg, M., Gneezy, U., Güth, W., & Van Damme, E. (2001). Direct vs indirect reciprocity: An experiment. Homo Oeconomicus, 18, 19–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Falk, A., Fehr, E., & Fischbacher, U. (2003). On the nature of fair behavior. Economic Inquiry, 41(1), 20–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falk, A., & Fischbacher, U. (2006). A theory of reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 54, 293–315.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fearon, J. D., & Laitin, D. D. (1996). Explaining interethnic cooperation. American Political Science Review, 90(4), 715–735.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Gächter, S. (2000). Cooperation and punishment in public goods experiments. American Economic Review, 90(4), 980–994.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fershtman, C., & Gneezy, U. (2001). Discrimination in a segmented society: An experimental approach. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(1), 351–377.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Econics, 10(2), 171–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischbacher, U., Gaechter, S., & F, E. (2001). Are people conditionally cooperative? Evidence from a public goods experiment. Economics Letters, 71(3), 397–404.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaertner, S. L., Dovidio, J. F., Anastasio, P. A., Bachman, B. A., & Rust, M. C. (1993). The common ingroup identity model: Recategorization and the reduction of intergroup bias. European Review of Social Psychology, 4(1), 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaertner, L., Iuzzini, J., & O’Mara, E. M. (2008). When rejection by one fosters aggression against many: Multiple-victim aggression as a consequence of social rejection and perceived groupness. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 44, 958–970.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser, E. L. (2005). The political economy of hatred. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(1), 45–86.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goette, L., Huffman, D., & Meier, S. (2006). The Impact of group membership on cooperation and norm enforcement: Evidence using random assignment to real social groups. American Economic Review, 96(2), 212–216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greiner, B. (2004). The Online Recruitment System ORSEE 2.0—A guide for the organization of experiments in economics.University of Cologne Working Papers Series in Economics, p. 10.

  • Greiner, B., & Levatti, V. M. (2005). Indirect reciprocity in cyclical networks. An experimental study. Journal of Economic Psychology, 26, 711–731.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guala, F. (2012). Reciprocity: Weak or strong? what punishment experiments do (and Do Not) demonstrate. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 35(1), 1.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Güth, W., Schmittberger, R., & Schwarze, B. (1982). An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 3(4), 367–388.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Habyarimana, J. P., Humphreys, M., Posner, D. N., & Weinstein, J. M. (2009). Coethnicity: Diversity and the dilemmas of collective action. New York: Russell Sage Foundation Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hardin, R. (1995). One for all: The logic of group conflict. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hargreaves-Heap, S., & Zizzo, D. J. (2009). The value of groups. American Economic Review, 99(1), 295–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoff, K., Kshetramade, M., & Fehr, E. (2011). Caste and punishment: The legacy of caste culture in norm enforcement. The Economic Journal, 121(556), F449–F475.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horowitz, D. N. (1985). Ethnic groups in conflict. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Horowitz, D. N. (2001). The deadly ethnic riot. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaufman, S. J. (2001). Modern hatreds: The symbolic politics of ethnic war. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J. M. (1922). The economic consequences of the peace. Los Angeles: IndoEuropean.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klein, J. G., & Ettensoe, R. (1999). Consumer animosity and consumer ethnocentrism. Journal of International Consumer Marketing, 11(4), 5–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leong, S. M., Cote, J. A., Ang, S. H., Tan, S. J., Jung, A. K., Kau, Keng, et al. (2008). Understanding consumer animosity in an international crisis: Nature, antecedents, and consequences. Journal of International Business Studies, 39(6), 996–1009.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lickel, B., Miller, N., Stenstrom, D. M., Denson, T. F., & Schmader, T. (2006). Vicarious retribution: The role of collective blame in intergroup aggression. Personality and Social Psychology Review, 10(2), 372–703.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mummendey, A., Simon, B., D, C., G, Melanie, Haeger, G., Kessler, S., et al. (1992). Categorization is not enough: Intergroup discrimination in negative outcome allocations. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 28, 125–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rabin, M. (1993). Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics. American Economic Review, 83(5), 1281–1302.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shayo, M., & Zussman, A. (2011). Judicial ingroup bias in the shadow of terrorism. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126(3), 1447–1484.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sherif, M., Harvey, O. J., Jack White, B., Hood, W. R., & Sherif, C. W. (1961). The Robbers cave experiment: Intergroup conflict and cooperation. Scranton: Wesleyan University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stanca, L. (2009). Measuring indirect reciprocity: Whose back do we scratch? Journal of Economic Psychology, 30(2), 190–202.

  • Stenstrom, D. M., Lickel, B., Denson, T. F., & Miller, N. (2008). The roles of ingroup identification and outgroup entitativity in intergroup retribution. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 34, 1570–1582.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tambiah, S. J. (1996). Leveling crowds: Ethnonationalist conflicts and collective violence in South Asia. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weisel, O., and Zultan, R. (2013). Social motives in intergroup conflict. Jena Economic Research Papers 2013-033.

  • Zussman, A. (2012). Ethnic Discrimination: Lessons from the israeli online market for used cars. Working paper.

Download references

Acknowledgements

This work was supported by British Academy Small Research Grant SG101553. We thank Astrid Buba, Vittoria Levati, Werner Güth, Eva Steiger, Johannes Weisser, Ro’i Zultan, David Reinstein, Ryan McKay, Eva van den Broek, Shaun Hargreaves Heap, Brian Lickel, Arthur Lupia, Tore Ellingsen, Lorenz Goette, Alicia Melis, Michelle Brock, Catherine Scacco, Rafael Hortalla-Vallve, Nadine Chlass, Matthew Braham and seminar participants at the Max Planck Institute of Economics, University of Hamburg, University of Warwick, King’s College London, University of East Anglia, NYU-CESS, IMEBE, ESA and THEEM for helpful comments; and the Max Planck Institute ESI group hiwis and administrative staff: Martin Beck, Nadine Erdmann, Adrian Liebtrau, Christian Williges, Christian Streubel, Claudia Zellmann and especially Christoph Göring.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Martin Alois Leroch.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hugh-Jones, D., Leroch, M.A. Intergroup Revenge: A Laboratory Experiment. Homo Oecon 34, 117–135 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s41412-017-0049-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s41412-017-0049-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation