Skip to main content
Log in

Institutions and policies of economic freedom: different effects on income and growth

  • Published:
Economia Politica Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The aim of this paper is to provide some additional results concerning how economic freedom enhances growth and/or long-run income. Our hypothesis is that institutions and policies of economic freedom may have different effects on long-run income and growth, both in terms of their size and working mechanisms. To test our hypothesis, we apply both Acemoglu et al.’s (Am Econ Rev 91(5):1369–401, 2001) and Mankiw et al.’s (Q J Econ 107(2):407–437, 1992) modeling strategies in our cross-country regression analyses. The major finding is that the institutions of economic freedom are of primary importance in economic development: they matter both in the long run and during the catching up period, and have both direct and indirect effects. On the other hand, the effects of economic freedom policies (monetary and fiscal) matter only during the catching up period, with the fiscal policy having a more straightforward effect. Furthermore, the estimates from the two modeling strategies are in line with each other, which can be seen as a further corroboration of our results.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The empirical studies we will refer to in what follows measure economic freedom either by the Fraser Institute’s Economic Freedom of the World (EFW) index or the Heritage Foundation and The Wall Street Journal’s Index of Economic Freedom.

  2. In the majority of cases, the areas and/or sub-areas of an economic freedom index are used as ‘components’ of economic freedom. Most of the papers we review in Sect. 2 use some of the five areas of the Fraser Institute’s Economic Freedom of the World Index, which include (1) size of government, (2) legal structure and security of property rights, (3) sound money, (4) freedom to exchange with foreigners, and (5) regulation of credit, labor, and business (Gwartney and Lawson 2003c). Those papers, however, which deal with the index before the publication of the 2002 report relate to an index with seven components, which include: (1) size of government, (2) structure of the economy and use of markets, (3) monetary policy and price stability, (4) freedom to use alternative currencies, (5) legal structure and property rights, (6) international exchange: freedom to trade with foreigners, and (7) freedom of exchange in capital and financial markets (Gwartney and Lawson 2001, p. 6).

  3. For a more detailed review of the literature see the aforementioned paper of Hall and Lawson (2014), Bologna and Hall (2014), Czeglédi and Kapás (2009, pp. 33–59), or Berggren (2003).

  4. Note that there are, of course, counterarguments as well, such as De Haan and Sturm’s (2006), which says that economic freedom is a latent variable, and what we want is the best estimate of this variable, and in order to find the best proxy we must use various measures and ‘components’.

  5. It has to be noted that our measures of the institutions and policies of economic freedom are ‘constrained’ by the EFW index itself, and may be slightly different from the concepts of institutions and policies used in the literature.

  6. See Baumol (1990) on the distinction between productive and unproductive entrepreneurship.

  7. Available at: http://www.barrolee.com/.

  8. Available at: http://www.cid.harvard.edu/ciddata/geographydata.htm.

  9. Barbados, Fiji, Hong Kong, Mauritius, Singapore.

  10. Available at: https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/.

  11. Some databases, including the Freedom House (2013) do not provide data for Germany before 1990, only for West and East Germany. In these cases we used the population-weighted averages of the two Germanys’ data.

  12. Available at: http://scholar.harvard.edu/barro/publications/religion-adherence-data.

  13. Note that our result that there is no reverse causality between the economic freedom institutions and income runs counter to some arguments (e.g., Heitger 2004) which maintain that property rights, as an important part of institutions and development, improve together with economic development in a virtuous circle (or deteriorate in a vicious one). A possible explanation for our result may be that our institutions variable includes more than property rights, most importantly regulatory variables, which may degrade the positive effects of property rights.

  14. This finding refines what has been shown by others (e.g. Gwartney et al. 2006), as well.

  15. There are political-economic reasons to believe that a fragmentation of the polity leads to a lower quality economic policy. See, for example, the famous model of Alesina and Tabellini (1990).

  16. Although including so many instruments may weaken the strength of our argument, the formal statistics of the instruments suggest otherwise, since the usual formal tests say that our instruments are relevant and valid. The first stage regressions and the instruments’ validation statistics are available upon request.

  17. It must be emphasized, once again, that our definition of what constitutes institutions and economic policy is constrained by the EFW index, and of course the index itself does not necessarily contain all the elements which are usually thought of as constituting these institutions and policy.

  18. The dataset consists of long-run data for the following 21 countries: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Japan, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, the United States, the United Kingdom, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, and Switzerland. Considering the component ‘property rights’, an augmented Dickey–Fuller test rejects the presence of a unit root at the 5% significance level in nine cases: Austria, Belgium, Canada, Germany, the Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Sweden, Switzerland. For the component of ‘international trade’ the unit root is rejected in three cases: Belgium, Greece, and New Zealand. Finally, for the component ‘regulation’, the unit root hypothesis is rejected in 16 cases: Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, the United States, the United Kingdom, Spain, Sweden, and Switzerland.

  19. See footnote 18.

References

  • Acemoglu, D., & Johnson, S. (2005). Unbundling institutions. Journal of Political Economy, 113(5), 949–995.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2001). The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation. American Economic Review, 91(5), 1369–1401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., Devleeschauwer, A., Easterly, W., Kurlat, S., & Wacziarg, R. (2003). Fractionalization. Journal of Economic Growth, 8, 155–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., & Tabellini, G. (1990). A positive theory of fiscal deficits and government debt. Review of Economic Studies, 57(3), 403–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ali, A. M., & Isse, H. S. (2003). Determinants of economic corruption: A cross-country comparison. Cato Journal, 22(3), 449–466.

    Google Scholar 

  • Altman, M. (2008). How much economic freedom is necessary for economic growth? Theory and Evidence. Economics Bulletin, 15(2), 1–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J. (1997). Determinants of Economic Growth: A Cross-Country Empirical Study. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J. (2000). Rule of law, democracy, and economic performance. In: O’ Driscoll, G. P., Holmes, K. R., Kirkpatrick, M. (Eds.), 2000 Index of Economic Freedom. Washington, D. C./New York: Heritage Foundation/The Wall Street Journal.

  • Barro, R. J. (2003). Religion Adherence Data. http://scholar.harvard.edu/barro/publications/religion-adherence-data. Accessed 13 Jan 2015.

  • Barro, R., & Lee, J.-W. (2013). A new data set of educational attainment in the world, 1950–2010. Journal of Development Economics, 104, 184–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W. J. (1990). Entrepreneurship: Productive, unproductive and destructive. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), 893–919.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berggren, N. (2003). The benefits of economic freedom: A survey. Independent Review, 8(2), 193–211.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berggren, N., & Jordahl, H. (2005). Does free trade really reduce growth? Further testing using the economic freedom index. Public Choice, 122(1–2), 99–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berggren, N., & Jordahl, H. (2006). Free to trust: Freedom and social capital. Kyklos, 59(2), 141–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergh, A., & Karlsson, M. (2010). Government size and growth: Accounting for economic freedom and globalization. Public Choice, 142, 195–213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharyya, S. (2009). Unbundled institutions, human capital and growth. Journal of Comparative Economics, 37(1), 106–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjørnskov, Ch., & Foss, N. J. (2012). How institutions of liberty promote entrepreneurship and growth. In: J. Gwartney, R. Lawson, J. Hall (Eds.), Economic Freedom of the World: 2012 Annual Report (pp. 247–270). Vancouver: Fraser Institute.

  • Boettke, P. J., & Coyne, C. J. (2003). Entrepreneurship and development: Cause and consequence. In: R. Koppl (Ed.), Austrian Economics and Entrepreneurial Studies. Advances in Austrian Economics, vol. 6 (pp. 67–88). Oxford: JAI Press.

  • Boettke, P. J., Coyne, C. J., & Leeson, P. T. (2008). Institutional stickiness and the new development economics. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 67(2), 331–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J., & Fink, A. (2011). Institutions first. Journal of Institutional Economics, 7(4), 499–504.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bologna, J., & Hall, J. C. (2014). Economic freedom research: Some comments and suggestions. In: J. C. Hall (Ed.), The Annual Proceedings of the Wealth and Well-Being of Nations, vol. VI (2013–2014) (pp. 123–135). Beloit: Beloit College Press.

  • Carlsson, F., & Lundström, S. (2002). Economic freedom and growth: Decomposing the effects. Public Choice, 112(3–4), 335–344.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caudill, S. B., Zanella, F., & Mixon, F. G., Jr. (2000). Is economic freedom one dimensional? A factor analysis of some common measures of economic freedom. Journal of Economic Development, 25(1), 17–39.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coyne, C. J., Sobel, R. S., & Dove, J. A. (2010). The non-productive entrepreneurial process. Journal of Austrian Economics, 23(4), 333–346.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Czeglédi, P., & Kapás, J. (2009). Economic Freedom and Development. An Austrian Economics Perspective. Budapest: Akadémiai Kiadó.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dawson, J. W. (1998). Institutions, investment, and growth: New cross-country and panel data evidence. Economic Inquiry, 36(4), 603–619.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dawson, J. W. (2003). Causality in the freedom–growth relationship. European Journal of Political Economy, 19(3), 479–495.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Haan, J., & Sturm, J. E. (2000). On the relationship between economic freedom and economic growth. European Journal of Political Economy, 16(2), 215–241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Haan, J., & Sturm, J. E. (2003). Does more democracy lead to greater economic freedom? New evidence for developing countries. European Journal of Political Economy, 19(3), 547–563.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Haan, J., & Sturm, J. E. (2006). How to handle economic freedom: Reply to Lawson. Economic Journal Watch, 3(3), 407–410.

    Google Scholar 

  • Doucouliagos, Ch., & Ulubasoglu, M. A. (2006). Economic freedom and economic growth: Does specification make a difference? European Journal of Political Economy, 2(1), 60–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durham, B. J. (1999). Economic growth and political regimes. Journal of Economic Growth, 4, 81–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterly, W. (2005). National policies and economic growth. A reappraisal. In Ph Aghion & S. N. Durlauf (Eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth (Vol. 1A, pp. 1015–1059). Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterly, W. (2013). The Tyranny of Experts: Economists, Dictators, and the Forgotten Rights of the Poor. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterly, W., & Levine, R. (2001). It is not factor accumulation: Stylized facts and growth models. World Bank Economic Review, 15(2), 177–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterly, W., & Levine, R. (2003). Tropics, germs and crops: How endowments influence economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 50(1), 3–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterly, W., & Levine, R. (2016). The European origins of economic development. Journal of Economic Growth, 21(3), 225–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easton, S. T., & Walker, M. A. (1997). Income, growth, and economic freedom. American Economic Review, 87(2), 328–332.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freedom House. (2013). Freedom in the World Country Ratings 1972–2012. Washington, D. C.: Freedom House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (1962). Capitalism and Freedom. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gallup, J. L., Sachs, J. D., & Mellinger, A. D. (1999). Geography and economic development. In: Working Paper, Center for Economic Development at Harvard University.

  • Glaeser, E. L., La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2004). Do institutions cause growth? Journal of Economic Growth, 9(3), 271–303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grubel, H. G. (1998). Economic freedom and human welfare: Some empirical findings. Cato Journal, 18(2), 287–304.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gwartney, J. D., Holcombe, R. G., & Lawson, R. A. (2004). Economic freedom, institutional quality, and cross-country differences in income and growth. Cato Journal, 24(3), 205–233.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gwartney, J. D., Holcombe, R. G., & Lawson, R. A. (2006). Institutions and the impact of investment on growth. Kyklos, 59(2), 255–273.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gwartney, J. D., & Lawson, R. A. (2001). Economic freedom of the world 2001 annual report. Vancouver: The Fraser Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gwartney, J. D., & Lawson, R. A. (2003a). What have we learned from the measurement of economic freedom. In M. A. Wynne, H. Rosenblum, & R. L. Formiani (Eds.), The Legacy of Milton and Rose Friedman’s Free to Choose: Economic Liberalism at the Turn of the 21st Century (pp. 217–238). Dallas: Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gwartney, J. D., & Lawson, R. A. (2003b). The concept and measurement of economic freedom. European Journal of Political Economy, 19(3), 405–430.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gwartney, J. D., & Lawson, R. A. (2003c). Economic Freedom of the World 2003 Annual Report. Vancouver: The Fraser Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gwartney, J. D., Lawson, R., & Hall, J. (2012). Economic freedom of the world. In: Annual Report 2012. Vancouver: The Fraser Institute.

  • Hall, R. E., & Jones, Ch I. (1999). Why do some countries produce so much more output than others? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(1), 83–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, J. C., & Lawson, R. A. (2014). Economic freedom of the world: An accounting for the literature. Contemporary Economics Policy, 32(1), 1–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1960). The Constitution of Liberty. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heitger, B. (2004). Property rights and the wealth of nations: A cross-country study. Cato Journal, 23(3), 381–402.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heston, A., Summers, R., & Aten, B. (2012). Penn World Table Version 7.1. Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices, University of Pennsylvania.

  • Hillman, A. L., & Potrafke, N. (2017). Economic freedom and religion: An empirical investigation. Public Finance Review (forthcoming, first published 21 Sep 2016). doi:10.1177/1091142116665901.

  • Horwitz, S. (2000). Microfoundations and Macroeconomics. An Austrian Perspective. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ikeda, S. (1997). Dynamics of the Mixed Economy: Toward a Theory of Interventionism. New York: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Justesen, M. K. (2008). The effect of economic freedom on growth revisited: New evidence on causality from a panel of countries. European Journal of Political Economy, 24, 542–660.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lawson, R. A. (2006). On testing the connection between economic freedom and growth. Economic Journal Watch, 3(3), 398–406.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw, G., Romer, D., & Weil, D. N. (1992). A contribution to the empirics of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(2), 407–437.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey, D. N. (2010). Bourgeois Dignity. Why Economics Can’t Explain the Modern World. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey, D. N. (2016). Bourgeois Equality: How Ideas, Not Capital or Institutions, Enriched the Modern World. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr, J. (2017). A Culture of Growth: Origins of the Modern Economy. Princeton: Princeton University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, K. M., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1993). Why is rent-seeking so costly to growth? American Economic Review, 83(2), 409–414.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Nyström, K. (2008). The institutions of economic freedom and entrepreneurship: Evidence from panel data. Public Choice, 136(3–4), 269–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1996). Big bills left on the sidewalk: Why some nations are rich, and others are poor? Journal of Economic Perspective, 10(2), 3–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (1986). An agenda for the study of institutions. Public Choice, 48, 3–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prados de la Escosura, L. (2016). Economic freedom in the long run: Evidence from OECD countries (1850–2007). Economic History Review, 69(2), 435–468.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Richter, R. (2015). Essays on New Institutional Economics. Cham: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D., Subramanian, A., & Trebbi, F. (2004). Institutions rule: The primacy of institutions over geography and integration in economic development. Journal of Economic Growth, 9(2), 131–165.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg, N., & Birdzell, L. E., Jr. (1986). How the West Grew Rich: The Economic Transformation of the Industrial World. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sachs, J. D. (2003). Institutions don’t rule: Direct effects of geography on per capita income. In: NBER Working Paper No. 9490.

  • Scully, G. W. (2002). Economic freedom, government policy and the trade-off between equity and economic growth. Public Choice, 113(1–2), 77–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sobel, R. S., & Coyne, C. J. (2011). Cointegrating institutions: The time-series properties of country institutional measures. Journal of Law and Economics, 54(2), 111–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Storr, V. H. (2013). Understanding the Culture of Markets. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Judit Kapás.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 A comparison of the long-run and the short-run estimates

In Sect. 4.4 we made four assumptions in order to be able to compare our short-run estimate with the long-run one. The first two assumptions can be summarized by saying that the change in log income can be written as

$$\Delta \ln y_{2010} = \sum\limits_{t = 1801}^{2010} {\hat{\alpha }_{5} \Delta \ln (inst)_{t} }$$

where Δln(inst) t is the change in the economic freedom institutions in year t, and \(\hat{\alpha }_{5}\) is the estimation for the effect of economic freedom institutions on the growth rate we derived from the analysis of the period 1980–2010.

The third assumption we made concerns the time series economic freedom institutions follow in the long-run. To be able to make a meaningful estimation of the long-run effect from the short-run one, we have to consider what happens to the measure of economic freedom institutions in the periods we are not able to observe. The regression results on the growth rate can be understood as what would happen if the measure of economic freedom institutions (ln institutions) was increased by one unit at the beginning of a 30-year period and remained at this higher level until this period ends. This 30-year period is just the last 30 years of the long period in question (210 years), and a one-unit difference for this last 30 years does not imply the same difference for the preceding 180 years. It is therefore meaningful to divide this long period into two parts:

$$\Delta \ln y_{2010} = \sum\limits_{t = 1801}^{1980} {\hat{\alpha }_{5} \Delta \ln (inst)_{t} } + \sum\limits_{t = 1981}^{2010} {\hat{\alpha }_{5} \Delta \ln (inst)_{t} } = \hat{\alpha }_{5} \left[ {\sum\limits_{t = 1801}^{1980} {\Delta \ln (inst)_{t} } + 30} \right]$$

To be able to make an educated guess about the difference in economic freedom institutions before 1980, we assume a time series which institutions follow. Suppose that this process is a stationary one for country j as follows:

$$\ln (inst)_{jt} = \theta \ln (inst)_{jt - 1} + \varepsilon_{jt}$$

with θ being the autoregressive parameter to be estimated from the long-run data of economic freedom, while ε t is the error term. Therefore, the difference in economic freedom institutions between two countries follows the process:

$$\Delta \ln (inst)_{t} = \theta \Delta \ln (inst)_{t - 1} + \varepsilon_{t}$$

Our assumptions above say that this difference is zero in 1800 and it is one in 1980. To make use of this, first note that the difference in a year t (1801 ≤ t ≤ 2010) is

$$\Delta \ln (inst)_{t} = \sum\limits_{k = 1801}^{t} {\theta^{t - k} \varepsilon_{k} }$$

Second, let us suppose that the one-unit difference observed in 1980 is the result of a slow and steady evolution of the institutions of economic freedom through which the same shock occurs each year:

$$\varepsilon_{1801} = \varepsilon_{1802} = \cdots \cdots = \varepsilon_{2010} \equiv \varepsilon$$

Thus, assuming a one-unit difference for 1980 implies assuming a value for ε because \(\Delta \ln (inst)_{1980} = \sum\limits_{k = 1801}^{1980} {\theta^{1980 - k} \varepsilon = } \sum\limits_{l = 0}^{179} {\theta^{l} \varepsilon = } \frac{{1 - \theta^{180} }}{1 - \theta }\varepsilon = 1\), that is \(\varepsilon = \frac{1 - \theta }{{1 - \theta^{180} }}\).

In this way the expression for the income differences becomes:

$$\Delta \ln y_{2010} = \hat{\alpha }_{5} \left[ {\sum\limits_{t = 1801}^{1980} {\Delta \ln (inst)_{t} } + 30} \right] = \hat{\alpha }_{5} \left[ {\sum\limits_{t = 1801}^{1980} {\sum\limits_{k = 1801}^{t} {\theta^{t - k} \varepsilon } } + 30} \right]$$
$$= \hat{\alpha }_{5} \left[ {\sum\limits_{t = 1801}^{1980} {\frac{{ \, 1 - \theta^{t - 1800} }}{1 - \theta }} \frac{1 - \theta }{{1 - \theta^{180} }} + 30} \right] = \hat{\alpha }_{5} \left[ {\sum\limits_{l = 1}^{180} {\frac{{1 - \theta^{l} }}{1 - \theta } + 30} } \right] = \hat{\alpha }_{5} \left[ {\frac{180}{{1 - \theta^{180} }} - \frac{\theta }{1 - \theta } + 30} \right]$$

When examining the long-run data of Prados de la Escosura (2016) we find that in quite a few countries among the 21, the relevant component is stationary.Footnote 18 Using these long-run data, the value of θ, as averaged over the “stationary countries”, is estimated to be about 0.997, which gives the final result:

$$\Delta \ln y_{2010} = \hat{\alpha }_{5} [98.573 + 30] = \hat{\alpha }_{5} \times 128.573$$

As the estimated value of α 5 runs between 0.028 and 0.079 in Tables 3 and 4, this gives an estimate between 3.600 and 10.157 for the income difference in 2010, which shows a substantial overlap with—although it is far from being the same as—the interval between 2.476 and 4.600, the range within which we estimated the effect of economic freedom institutions on income in Table 2.

The time series of economic freedom institutions might not be stationary, however. Using panel unit root tests and considering the overall index, rather than any of its individual components, Sobel and Coyne (2011) came to the conclusion that economic freedom follows a non-stationary process. As we saw,Footnote 19 even the components of economic freedom institutions found in the Prados de la Escosura (2016) database follow a non-stationary process in some of the 21 countries. In accordance with this, let us derive a similar estimate to the one made above, assuming a random walk process for economic freedom institutions:

$$\ln (inst)_{jt} = \ln (inst)_{jt - 1} + \varepsilon_{jt}$$

leading to the difference between our two hypothetical countries in the form:

$$\Delta \ln (inst)_{t} = \sum\limits_{k = 1801}^{t} \varepsilon = (t - 1800)$$

For 1980, this becomes

Δln(inst)1980 = 180ɛ = 1, implying that ɛ = 1/180.

With the help of this we can again derive an educated guess for the income difference:

$$\Delta \ln y_{2010} = \hat{\alpha }_{5} \left[ {\sum\limits_{t = 1801}^{1980} {(t - 1800)\varepsilon } + 30} \right] = \hat{\alpha }_{5} \left[ {\sum\limits_{l = 1}^{180} {l\varepsilon } + 30} \right] = \hat{\alpha }_{5} \left[ {180 \times \frac{180 + 1}{2} \times \frac{1}{180} + 30} \right]$$

Which, finally, is

$$\Delta \ln y_{2010} = \hat{\alpha }_{5} [90.5 + 30] = \hat{\alpha }_{5} \times 120.5$$

Using the numbers from Tables 3 and 4 we now end up with an interval of 3.374–9.520 as an alternative estimate of what we have already estimated in Table 2. This interval shows a slightly greater overlap with our estimation.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kapás, J., Czeglédi, P. Institutions and policies of economic freedom: different effects on income and growth. Econ Polit 34, 259–282 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40888-017-0063-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40888-017-0063-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation