Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Bureaucratic efficiency, economic reform and informal sector

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Eurasian Economic Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, we develop a four sector general equilibrium model of a small open economy with three formal sectors and one informal sector. One formal sector’s output is used as an intermediate input in all other sectors. This intermediate input is defined here as bureaucracy. We have also incorporated an additional cost specific to the informal sector in addition to factor cost of production which is defined as the cost of corruption. In this context, this paper examines the impact of less protectionist policy and bureaucratic reform on the output levels and factor prices. It has been shown that the informal sector and manufacturing sector have contracted due to tariff reduction while informal wage goes up. Further, we have examined the effect of a decrease in bureaucratic (in)efficiency. This reduces the informal wage rate but informal sector expands. It is further examined that the effect of a decrease in the cost of corruption leads to an increase in the informal wage rate.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The objectives of Ease of Doing Business are to make government business rules and regulations more accessible, transparent, predictable and much easier. Doing business does cover important areas including obtaining a building permit, getting an electricity connection, transferring property, paying taxes, as well as credit and equity market regulations, etc. Ease of doing business indicator mainly focuses on the interaction between the government and entrepreneurs and it measures the quality of governance and property rights. It influences the policymakers and regulators to help producers to facilitate their interaction for smooth functioning. It is an index which computes the distance to frontier scores of different economies. This score uses the regulatory best practices for doing business as a parameter. In 2018, India has ranked 100 in the World Bank Ease of Doing Business Ranking (World Bank 2018).

  2. We will again define bureaucracy in more detail in Sect. 2 to suit the motive of our study.

  3. Though India is not making much progress in stamping out corruption, its progress in this front corroborates this claim. According to the 2016 Corruption Perceptions Index reported by Transparency International, India ranks 79th out of 175 countries. Corruption Rank in India averaged 75.32 from 1995 until 2016, reaching an all-time high of 95 in 2011 and a record low of 35 in 1995. The Corruption Perceptions Index ranks countries and territories based on how corrupt their public sector is perceived to be.

  4. This type of scenario is often observed in any typical developing economies such as India. Our model is designed in the backdrop of India where informal activities are rampant and provide employment to almost 92% of the workforce. Also not to forget that the economy is vastly distorted with corruption and bureaucracy related intermediation that naturally hinders the process of economic activities and growth in general.

  5. Specific capital is defined here as tools, computers or other kinds of equipment used in producing information capital. Information capital is usually described as a set of data values for the organization such as computer databases, libraries, information sharing networks etc.

  6. We are thankful to the referee for asking us to clarify this point.

  7. In this connection, it is very important to note that one may easily think of \(\overline{W}\) as not constant. The value of formal wage may depend on the informal wage in the sense that the formal wage is set over the informal wage through a constant value \(\alpha > 1\). Mathematically, \(\bar{W} = \alpha W > W\) as \(\alpha > 1\). This would, must be slightly different from what we have done here. We are grateful to an anonymous referee for pointing out this possibility. We hope to use this parameterization in our future works.

  8. We are very thankful to the referee for suggesting us how to relate the findings with existing literature. This will help us in our future works.

  9. M is more capital intensive than I in comparison with labor. \(\left( {\lambda_{LM} \lambda_{KI} - \lambda_{KM} \lambda_{LI} } \right) < 0.\) M is more capital intensive than Y in comparison with labor. \(\left( {\lambda_{KM} \lambda_{LY} - \lambda_{KY} \lambda_{LM} } \right) > 0.\) And Y is more capital intensive than I in comparison with labor. \(\left( {\lambda_{KY} \lambda_{LI} - \lambda_{KI} \lambda_{LY} } \right) > 0.\)

  10. M is more capital intensive than I in comparison with labor. \(\left( {\lambda_{KM} \lambda_{LI} - \lambda_{LM} \lambda_{KI} } \right) > 0.\) M is also more capital intensive than Y in comparison with labor. \(\left( {\lambda_{KY} \lambda_{LM} - \lambda_{KM} \lambda_{LY} } \right) < 0.\) And Y is more capital intensive than I in comparison with labor. \(\left( {\lambda_{KI} \lambda_{LY} - \lambda_{KY} \lambda_{LI} } \right) < 0.\)

References

  • Acemoglu, D., Ticch, D., & Vindigni, A. (2011). Emergence and persistence of inefficient states. Journal of the European Economic Association, 9(2), 177–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Agenor, R., & Montiel, P. (1997). Development macroeconomics (2nd ed.). NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, J. E., & Wincoop, E. V. (2001). Borders, trade and welfare. NBER Working Paper No. 8515.

  • Anderson, J., & Marcouiller, D. (2002). Insecurity and the pattern of trade: An empirical investigation. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 84(2), 342–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anitha, V. (2007). Efficiency and bureaucracy. Working paper No. 181, Institute for Social and Economic Change.

  • Basu, K. (1986). One kind of power. Oxford Economic Papers, 38, 259–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertrand, M., Burges, R., Chawla, A., & Xu, G. (2016). The cost of bureaucratic rigidity, evidence from the Indian Administrative Service. Mimeo: University of Chicago.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bose, G. (2004). Bureaucratic delays and bribe-taking. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 54(3), 313–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bose, G. (2010). Aspects of Bureaucratic Corruption. Discussion Papers 2010/14. Australia: School of Economics, The University of New South Wales.

  • Bose, G., & Gangopadhyay, S. (2009). Intermediation in corruption markets. Indian Growth and Development Review, 2(1), 39–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chaudhuri, S., & Gupta, M. R. (1996). Delayed formal credit, bribing and the informal credit market in agriculture: A theoretical analysis. Journal of Development Economics, 51(2), 433–449.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chaudhuri, S., & Mandal, B. (2012). Bureaucratic reform, informal sector and welfare. Working Paper, MPRA no. 36072.

  • Coatsworth, J. H. (1993). Notes on the Comparative Economic History of Latin America and the United States. In W. L. Bernecker & H. W. Tobler (Eds.), Development and Underdevelopment in America: Contrasts of Economic Growth in North and Latin America in Historical Perspective (pp. 10–30). Berlin: de Gruyter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coatsworth, J. H. (1998). Economic and institutional trajectories in nineteenth-century Latin America. In J. H. Coatsworth & A. M. Taylor (Eds.), Latin America and the world economy since 1800. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dutta, N., Kar, S., & Roy, S. (2013). Corruption and Persistent Informality: An Empirical Investigation for Indian States. International Review of Economics and Finance, 27, 357–373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Efendic, A., Pugh, G., & Adnett, N. (2011). Institutions and Economic Performance: A Meta Regression Analysis. European Journal of Political Economy, 27(3), 586–599.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elgin, C., & Erturk, F. (2018). Informal economies around the world: Measures, determinants and consequences. Eurasian Economic Review (Forthcoming).

  • Engerman, S. L., & Sokoloff, K. L. (1997). Factor endowments, institutions, and differential paths of growth among new world economies: a view from economic historians of the United States. In S. Harber (Ed.), How Latin America Fell Behind. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerxhani, K. (2004). The informal sector in developed and less developed countries: A literature survey. Public Choice, 120, 267–300.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gupta, M. R., & Chaudhuri, S. (1997). Formal credit, corruption and the informal credit market in agriculture: A theoretical analysis. Economica, 64(254), 331–343.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, S., Kaufman, D., & Shleifer, A. (1997). The unofficial economy in transition. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 28(2), 159–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, A. (1974). The political economy of the rent-seeking society. American Economic Review, 64, 291–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lambsdorff, J. (1998). An empirical investigation of bribery in international trade. European Journal of Development Research, 10(1), 40–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ligthelm, A. (2011). Survival analysis of small informal businesses in South Africa, 2007–2010. Eurasian Economic Review, 1(2), 160–179.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mandal, B., Marjit, S., & Beladi, H. (2018). Reform, informal sector and extortion. Economics and Politics, 30(1), 106–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marjit, S., & Kar, S. (2011). The outsiders: Economic reform and informal labor in a developing economy. New Delhi, London: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Marjit, S., & Mandal, B. (2012). Domestic trading costs and pure theory of international trade. International Journal of Economic Theory, 8(2), 165–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mauro, P. (1995). Corruption and Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(3), 681–712.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1988). Institutions, economic growth and freedom: An historical introduction. In M. A. Walker (Ed.), Freedom, democracy and economic welfare. Vancouver: Frase Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schneider, F., & Enste, D. H. (2000). Shadow economies: Size, causes and consequences. Journal of Economic Literature, 38(1), 77–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1993). Corruption. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108, 599.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spinesi, L. (2009). Rent-seeking bureaucracies, inequality and growth. Journal of Development Economics, 90(2), 244–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stroup, C., & Zissimos, B. (2017). Pampered bureaucracy, political stability and trade integration. Review of Development Economics, 21(3), 425–450.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (1922). Economy and society, 4th edition (republished 1956), University of California Press, Tubingen.

  • Wei, S.-J. (1997). How taxing is corruption on international investors? The Review of Economics and Statistics, 82(1), 1–11.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (2018). Doing business in the world: Understanding regulation. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sujata Ghosh.

Additional information

This paper is a revised version of an earlier draft with the same title. We are thankful to the seminar participants at St. Xavier’s College, Bengal Economic Association, Visva Bharati University for their constructive comments. We also gratefully acknowledge the constructive comments from two anonymous referees and the editor. Those comments were very helpful in reshaping and refining our basic ideas. The paper is based on a part of the PhD thesis of Sujata Ghosh. The usual disclaimer applies.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Tariff reform or a reduction in t

Differentiating Eqs. (1) (2), (3) and (4) using envelope condition, we get,

$$\hat{R}\theta_{TY} + \hat{r}\theta_{KY} + \hat{P}_{G} \theta_{GY} = 0$$
(9)
$$\hat{r}\theta_{KM} + \hat{P}_{G} \theta_{GM} = \alpha \hat{t}$$
(10)
$$\hat{r}\theta_{KG} = \hat{P}_{G}$$
(11)
$$\hat{W}\theta_{LI} + \hat{r}\theta_{KI} + \hat{P}_{G} \theta_{GI} = 0$$
(12)

where,

$$\alpha = \frac{t}{1 + t}$$

From Eqs. (10) and (11), we get

$$\hat{P}_{G} = \frac{{\alpha \theta_{KG} }}{{\left[ {\theta_{KG} \theta_{GM} + \theta_{KM} } \right]}}\hat{t}\quad {\text{and}}\quad \hat{r} = \frac{\alpha }{{\left[ {\theta_{KG} \theta_{GM} + \theta_{KM} } \right]}}\hat{t}$$

\(\text{Let,} \quad \left[ {\theta_{KG} \theta_{GM} + \theta_{KM} } \right]\) = β

Therefore,

$$\hat{P}_{G} = \frac{{\alpha \theta_{KG} }}{\beta }\hat{t}$$
(13)
$$\hat{r} = \frac{\alpha }{\beta }\hat{t}$$
(14)

Using Eq. (13) in Eq. (9), it becomes

$$\hat{R} = - \frac{\alpha }{\beta }\frac{{\left( {\theta_{KY} + \theta_{KG} \theta_{GY} } \right)}}{{\theta_{TY} }}\hat{t}$$
(15)

Using the values of \(\hat{r}\) and \(\hat{P}_{G}\) in Eq. (12), we obtain

$$\hat{W} = - \frac{\alpha }{{\beta \theta_{LI} }}\left[ {\theta_{KI} + \theta_{KG} \theta_{GI} + \theta_{KG} } \right]\hat{t}$$

\( \text{Let,} \quad \frac{1}{{\theta_{LI} }}\left[ {\theta_{KI} + \theta_{KG} \theta_{GI} + \theta_{KG} } \right] = \delta\)

$${\text{Therefore}},\,\, \hat{W} = - \frac{\alpha }{\beta }\delta \hat{t}$$
(16)

Differentiating Eq. (7) and using elasticity of substitution

$$\hat{X}_{Y} = - \sigma_{Y} \theta_{LY} \left( {\hat{\bar{W}} - \hat{R}} \right)$$

Using the values of Eq. (15) in the above equation, it becomes

$$\hat{X}_{Y} = - A_{1} \hat{t} > 0\,\,{\text{as}}\,\,\hat{t} < 0$$
(17)

where \(A_{1} = \left[ {\sigma_{Y} \theta_{LY} \frac{{\left( {\theta_{KY} + \theta_{KG} \theta_{GY} } \right)}}{{\theta_{TY} }}\frac{\alpha }{\beta }} \right] > 0\)

Differentiating Eq. (5) and substituting the values from Eq. (17)

$$\lambda_{LM} \hat{X}_{M} + \lambda_{LG} \hat{X}_{G} + \lambda_{LI} \hat{X}_{I} = \lambda_{LY} A_{1} \hat{t}$$
(18)

From Eqs. (6) and (18), we get

$$\lambda_{KM} \hat{X}_{M} + \lambda_{KG} \hat{X}_{G} + \lambda_{KI} \hat{X}_{I} = \lambda_{KY} A_{1} \hat{t}$$
(19)

Equation (8) yields

$$\lambda_{GM} \hat{X}_{M} + \lambda_{GI} \hat{X}_{I} - \hat{X}_{G} = - \lambda_{GY} \hat{X}_{Y}$$
(20)

Using the values of (17), the above equation becomes

$$\lambda_{GM} \hat{X}_{M} + \lambda_{GI} \hat{X}_{I} - \hat{X}_{G} = \lambda_{GY} A_{1} \hat{t}$$
(21)

In matrix representation Eqs. (18), (19) and (21) can be shown as

$$\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\lambda_{LM} } & {\lambda_{LI} } & {\lambda_{LG} } \\ {\lambda_{KM} } & {\lambda_{KI} } & {\lambda_{KG} } \\ {\lambda_{GM} } & {\lambda_{GI} } & { - 1} \\ \end{array} } \right]\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\hat{X}_{M} } \\ {\hat{X}_{I} } \\ {\hat{X}_{G} } \\ \end{array} } \right] = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\lambda_{LY} A_{1} \hat{t}} \\ {\lambda_{KY} A_{1} \hat{t}} \\ {\lambda_{GY} A_{1} \hat{t}} \\ \end{array} } \right]$$

Using the Cramer’s rule we can solve

$$\hat{X}_{M} = \frac{1}{\left| \lambda \right|}A_{1} A_{2} \hat{t}$$
(22)
$$\hat{X}_{I} = \frac{1}{\left| \lambda \right|}A_{1} A_{3} \hat{t}$$
(23)
$$\hat{X}_{G} = \frac{1}{\left| \lambda \right|}\left[ {\lambda_{GY} \left( {\lambda_{LM} \lambda_{KI} - \lambda_{KM} \lambda_{LI} } \right) + \lambda_{GI} \left( {\lambda_{KM} \lambda_{LY} - \lambda_{KY} \lambda_{LM} } \right) + \lambda_{GM} \left( {\lambda_{KY} \lambda_{LI} - \lambda_{KI} \lambda_{LY} } \right)} \right]A_{1} \hat{t}$$
(24)

Therefore, the effect on G is ambiguous which depends on the relative changes of other sectorsFootnote 9

$$A_{2} = \left[ {\left( {\lambda_{LI} \lambda_{KY} - \lambda_{LY} \lambda_{KI} } \right) + \lambda_{KG} \left( {\lambda_{LI} \lambda_{GY} - \lambda_{LY} \lambda_{GI} } \right) + \lambda_{GY} \left( {\lambda_{LI} \lambda_{KG} - \lambda_{LG} \lambda_{KI} } \right)} \right] > 0$$
$$A_{3} = \left[ {\left( {\lambda_{KM} \lambda_{LY} - \lambda_{LM} \lambda_{KY} } \right) + \lambda_{GY} \left( {\lambda_{KM} \lambda_{LG} - \lambda_{LM} \lambda_{KG} } \right) + \lambda_{GM} \left( {\lambda_{LY} \lambda_{KG} - \lambda_{LG} \lambda_{KY} } \right)} \right] > 0$$
$$\left| \lambda \right| = \lambda_{GM} \left( {\lambda_{LI} \lambda_{KG} - \lambda_{LG} \lambda_{KI} } \right) - \lambda_{GI} \left( {\lambda_{LM} \lambda_{KG} - \lambda_{LG} \lambda_{KM} } \right) - \left( {\lambda_{LM} \lambda_{KI} - \lambda_{LI} \lambda_{KM} } \right)$$

If

  1. (i)

    I is more labor-intensive than G in comparison with capital, \(\left( {\lambda_{LI} \lambda_{KG} - \lambda_{LG} \lambda_{KI} } \right)\) > 0;

  2. (ii)

    M is more capital-intensive than G in comparison with labor, \(\left( {\lambda_{LM} \lambda_{KG} - \lambda_{LG} \lambda_{KM} } \right)\) < 0;

  3. (iii)

    I is more labor-intensive than M in comparison with capital. \(\left( {\lambda_{LM} \lambda_{KI} - \lambda_{LI} \lambda_{KM} } \right)\) < 0.

Therefore, \(\left| \lambda \right| > 0\).

Appendix 2: A decrease in bureaucratic (in)efficiency (bureaucratic reform) E

Equations (2) and (3) would be modified as

$$\hat{r}\theta_{KM} + \hat{P}_{G} \theta_{GM} = 0$$
(25)
$$\hat{r}\theta_{KG} - \hat{P}_{G} = \hat{E}$$
(26)

Using Cramer’s rule and solving the equations, we obtain

$$\hat{r} = \frac{{\theta_{GM} }}{{\left( {\theta_{KM} + \theta_{KG} \theta_{GM} } \right)}}\hat{E}$$
(27)

And

$$\hat{P}_{G} = - \frac{{\theta_{KM} }}{{\left( {\theta_{KM} + \theta_{KG} \theta_{GM} } \right)}}\hat{E}$$
(28)

Using Eq. (28) in Eq. (9)

$$\hat{R} = \frac{{\left( {\theta_{KM} \theta_{GY} - \theta_{KY} \theta_{GM} } \right)}}{{\theta_{TY} \left( {\theta_{KM} + \theta_{KG} \theta_{GM} } \right)}}\hat{E}$$
(29)

Using the values of (27) and (28) in Eq. (12), it becomes

$$\hat{W} = \frac{{\theta_{KM} \theta_{GI} - \theta_{KI} \theta_{GM} }}{{\theta_{LI} \left( {\theta_{KM} + \theta_{KG} \theta_{GM} } \right)}}\hat{E}$$

Let,

$$B_{1} = \left[ {\frac{{\theta_{KM} \theta_{GI} - \theta_{KI} \theta_{GM} }}{{\left( {\theta_{KM} + \theta_{KG} \theta_{GM} } \right)}}} \right]$$

Therefore,

$$\hat{W} = \frac{1}{{\theta_{LI} }}B_{1} \hat{E}$$
(30)

Differentiating Eq. (7) and using the elasticity of substitution

$$\hat{X}_{Y} = - \sigma_{Y} \theta_{LY} \left( {\hat{\bar{W}} - \hat{R}} \right)$$

Using the values of Eq. (29) in the above equation, it becomes

$$\hat{X}_{Y} = B_{2} \hat{E}$$
(31)

where \(B_{2} = \left[ {\sigma_{Y} \theta_{LY} \frac{{\left( {\theta_{KM} \theta_{GY} - \theta_{KY} \theta_{GM} } \right)}}{{\theta_{TY} \left( {\theta_{KM} + \theta_{KG} \theta_{GM} } \right)}}} \right] > 0\)

Differentiating Eqs. (5), (6) and (8) and arranging them in matrix form to yield the following set of equations

$$\hat{X}_{M} = \frac{1}{\left| \lambda \right|}B_{2} B_{3} \hat{E}$$
(32)
$$\hat{X}_{I} = \frac{1}{\left| \lambda \right|}B_{2} B_{4} \hat{E}$$
(33)
$$\hat{X}_{G} = \frac{1}{\left| \lambda \right|}\left[ {\lambda_{GY} \left( {\lambda_{KM} \lambda_{LI} - \lambda_{LM} \lambda_{KI} } \right) + \lambda_{GI} \left( {\lambda_{LM} \lambda_{KY} - \lambda_{LY} \lambda_{KM} } \right) + \lambda_{GM} \left( {\lambda_{KI} \lambda_{LY} - \lambda_{LI} \lambda_{KY} } \right)} \right]B_{2} \hat{E}$$
(34)

Again, the effect on G is also ambiguousFootnote 10

$$B_{3} = \left[ {\left( {\lambda_{KI} \lambda_{LY} - \lambda_{LI} \lambda_{KY} } \right) + \lambda_{LG} \left( {\lambda_{KI} \lambda_{GY} - \lambda_{KY} \lambda_{GI} } \right) + \lambda_{GY} \left( {\lambda_{LG} \lambda_{KI} - \lambda_{KG} \lambda_{LI} } \right)} \right] < 0$$
$$B_{4} = \left[ {\left( {\lambda_{LM} \lambda_{KY} - \lambda_{KM} \lambda_{LY} } \right) + \lambda_{GY} \left( {\lambda_{LM} \lambda_{KG} - \lambda_{KM} \lambda_{LG} } \right) + \lambda_{GM} \left( {\lambda_{KY} \lambda_{LG} - \lambda_{LY} \lambda_{KG} } \right)} \right] < 0$$

\(\left| \lambda \right| > 0\). The values are the same as before.

Appendix 3: A decrease in cost of corruption u

Differentiating Eq. (4)

$$\hat{W}\left( {\frac{{\theta_{LI} }}{{\theta_{GI} }}} \right) + \hat{r}\left( {\frac{{\theta_{KI} }}{{\theta_{GI} }}} \right) + \hat{P}_{G} = - \hat{u}$$
(35)

Solving Eqs. (9), (25) and (11), we can get

$$\hat{r} = \hat{R} = \hat{P}_{G} = 0$$

From Eq. (35)

$$\hat{W} = - \hat{u}\left( {\frac{{\theta_{u} }}{{\theta_{LI} }}} \right) < 0\,\,\,as\,\,\,\,\hat{u} < 0$$
(36)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ghosh, S., Mandal, B. Bureaucratic efficiency, economic reform and informal sector. Eurasian Econ Rev 9, 121–137 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40822-018-0123-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40822-018-0123-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation