Advertisement

Eurasian Business Review

, Volume 7, Issue 3, pp 421–436 | Cite as

Institutions and gravity model: the role of political economy and corporate governance

  • Mehmet Huseyin Bilgin
  • Giray GozgorEmail author
  • Chi Keung Marco Lau
Original Paper

Abstract

Using panel data on 166 countries, this paper analyzes the effects of corporate governance, employment protection, investor protection, and political environments on the exporting performance. Our gravity model predicts that stronger democratic political institutions encourage exports. We also find that stronger rule-based corporate governance imposes positive impact on the export performance. We also note that stronger employee protection, and therefore, rigid labor regulations can distort the exporting decision of firms. In addition, a stronger shareholder protection tends to be associated with lower exports, probably attributed to lower innovative activity. We interpret these results as an indication that (i) countries with a higher quality of institution suffer from less formal and informal trade barriers, which make international trade relations easier, and (ii) both the employee protection and the shareholder protection, on the other hand, trivialize the country’s export.

Keywords

Exports Trade flows Gravity model Political institutions Employee protection Shareholder protection 

JEL Classification

F14 G34 K20 

References

  1. Anderson, J. E. (1979). A theoretical foundation for the gravity equation. American Economic Review, 69(1), 106–116.Google Scholar
  2. Anderson, J. E., & Marcouiller, D. (2002). Insecurity and the pattern of trade: an empirical investigation. Review of Economics and Statistics, 84(2), 342–352.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Anderson, J. E., & van Wincoop, E. (2003). Gravity with gravitas: a solution to the border puzzle. American Economic Review, 93(1), 170–192.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Arkolakis, K., Costinot, A., & Rodriguez-Clare, A. (2012). New trade models, same old gains? American Economic Review, 102(1), 94–130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Armington, P. S. (1969). A theory of demand for products distinguished by place of production. IMF Staff Papers, 16(1), 159–178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Belloc, M. (2006). Institutions and International Trade: a reconsideration of comparative advantage. Journal of Economic Surveys, 20(1), 3–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Belloc, F. (2013). Law, finance and innovation: the dark side of shareholder protection. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 37(4), 863–888.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Bergstrand, J. H. (1985). The gravity equation in international trade: some microeconomic foundations and empirical evidence. Review of Economics and Statistics, 67(3), 474–481.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Bergstrand, J. H. (1989). The generalized gravity equation, monopolistic competition and the factor-proportions theory in International Trade. Review of Economics and Statistics, 71(1), 143–153.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Berkowitz, D., Moenius, J., & Pistor, K. (2006). Trade, law, and product complexity. Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(2), 363–373.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Chaney, T. (2008). Distorted gravity: the intensive and extensive margins of international trade. American Economic Review, 98(4), 1707–1721.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Chowdhury, F., & Audretsch, D. B. (2014). Institution as looting apparatus: impact of Gender Equality and Institutions on Female Entrepreneurship. Eurasian Business Review, 4(2), 207–225.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Damijan, J. P., & Kostevc, C. (2015). Learning from trade through innovation. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 77(3), 408–436.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. De Groot, H. L. F., Linders, G.-J., Rietveld, P., & Subramanian, U. (2004). The Institutional Determinants of Bilateral Trade Patterns. Kyklos, 57(1), 103–123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Deardorff, A. V. (1998). Determinants of bilateral trade: does gravity work in a neoclassical world? In J. A. Frankel (Ed.), The regionalization of the world economy (pp. 7–22). Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  16. Depken, C. A., & Sonora, R. J. (2005). Asymmetric effects of economic freedom on international trade flows. International Journal of Business and Economics, 4(2), 141–155.Google Scholar
  17. Eaton, J., & Kortum, S. (2002). Technology, geography and trade. Econometrica, 70(5), 1741–1779.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Francois, J., & Manchin, M. (2013). Institutions, infrastructure, and trade. World Development, 46, 165–175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Gomez-Herrera, E. (2013). Comparing alternative methods to estimate gravity models of bilateral trade. Empirical Economics, 44(3), 1087–1111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Helpman, E., Melitz, M. J., & Rubinstein, Y. (2008). Trading partners and trade volumes. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(2), 441–487.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Koukhartchouk, O., & Maurel, M. (2003). Accession to the WTO and EU Enlargement: What Potential for Trade Increase? Center for Economic Policy Research Discussion Papers, No. 3944. London: Center for Economic Policy Research.Google Scholar
  22. Krugman, P. (1980). Scale economies, product differentiation and the pattern of trade. American Economic Review, 70(5), 950–959.Google Scholar
  23. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1997). Legal Determinants of External Finance. Journal of Finance, 52(3), 1131–1150.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1998). Law and Finance. Journal of Political Economy, 106(6), 1113–1155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Levchenko, A. A. (2007). Institutional Quality and International Trade. Review of Economic Studies, 74(3), 791–819.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Li, S., & Samsell, D. (2009). Why some countries trade more than others: the effect of the governance environment on trade flows. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 17(1), 47–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Linders, G.J.M., Slangen, A., de Groot, H.L.F., Beugelsdijk, S. (2005). Cultural and Institutional Determinants of Bilateral Trade Flows. Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper, No. TI 2005–074/3. Amsterdam: Tinbergen Institute.Google Scholar
  28. Mauro, P. (1995). Corruption and growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(3), 681–712.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Melitz, M. J. (2003). The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica, 71(6), 1695–1725.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Nicita, A., & Olarreaga, M. (2007). Trade, production, and protection database, 1976–2004. The World Bank Economic Review, 21(1), 165–171.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Nicoletti, G., & Scarpetta, S. (2001). Interaction between product and labour market regulations: do they affect employment? Evidence from the OECD Countries. Paper Presented at the Banco de Portugal Conference on Labour Market Institutions and Economic Outcomes. Lisbon.Google Scholar
  32. Nunn, N. (2007). Relationship-specificity, incomplete contracts, and the pattern of trade. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(2), 569–600.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Pagano, M., & Volpin, P. F. (2005). The political economy of corporate governance. American Economic Review, 95(4), 1005–1030.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Prasad, E.S., Rogoff, K., Wei, S.J., & Kose, M.A. (2003). Effects of Financial Globalization on Developing Countries: Some Empirical Evidence. IMF Occasional Paper, No. 220. Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
  35. Ranjan, P., & Lee, J. Y. (2007). Contract enforcement and international trade. Economics and Politics, 19(2), 191–218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Seker, M. (2012). Rigidities in employment protection and exporting. World Development, 40(2), 238–250.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1997). A survey of corporate governance. Journal of Finance, 52(2), 737–783.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Silva, J. S., & Tenreyro, S. (2006). The log of gravity. Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(4), 641–658.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Syriopoulos, T., & Tsatsaronis, M. (2012). Corporate governance mechanisms and financial performance: CEO duality in shipping firms. Eurasian Business Review, 2(1), 1–30.Google Scholar
  40. Tinbergen, J. (1962). Shaping the World Economy: suggestions for an International Economic Policy. New York: Twentieth Century Fund.Google Scholar
  41. United Nations and World Trade Organization. (2012). A practical guide to trade policy analysis. New York: United Nations Publications.Google Scholar
  42. Wang, L. F. S., & Han, T.-D. (2015). Better governance matters optimal privatization policy. Eurasian Economic Review, 5(2), 189–206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Wu, J., Li, S., & Samsell, D. (2012). Why some countries trade more, some trade less, some trade almost nothing: the effect of the governance environment on trade flows. International Business Review, 21(2), 225–238.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Yu, M. (2010). Trade, democracy, and the gravity equation. Journal of Development Economics, 91(2), 289–300.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Eurasia Business and Economics Society 2016

Authors and Affiliations

  • Mehmet Huseyin Bilgin
    • 1
  • Giray Gozgor
    • 1
    Email author
  • Chi Keung Marco Lau
    • 2
  1. 1.Faculty of Political SciencesIstanbul Medeniyet UniversityIstanbulTurkey
  2. 2.Newcastle Business SchoolNorthumbria UniversityNewcastle Upon TyneUK

Personalised recommendations