Abstract
Purpose of Review
This review focuses on recent developments in the application of behavioral economics to the evaluation of energy efficiency and greenhouse gas regulations. Transportation is the largest source of CO2 emissions from energy use in the US economy and a major and growing source worldwide. Regulating the efficiency of motor vehicles has been a core component of energy policy in the USA, the EU, China, Japan, Canada, and many other nations. Recent findings concerning consumers’ actual decision-making about energy efficiency indicate that the premises of the rational economic model are not appropriate for evaluating energy-efficiency standards.
Recent Findings
Progress in behavioral psychology and economics has shown that loss aversion, the principle that faced with a risky choice human beings tend to weigh potential losses about twice as heavily as gains, is strongly affected by framing. Simple, risky choices in which there is a status quo option generally provoke loss-averse responses. Recent analyses show that the choice to buy or not buy energy-efficiency technologies induces loss aversion and can result in systematic underinvestment in energy efficiency. Empirical investigation of consumers’ fuel economy decision-making contradicts the rational economic model and is consistent with loss aversion. However, recent economic evaluations of fuel economy and greenhouse gas regulations are explicitly or implicitly premised on rational economic behavior.
Summary
Insights developed by behavioral psychologists and behavioral economists about the decision-making of real consumers provide a coherent explanation that fundamentally alters the way fuel economy regulations should be evaluated. If consumers are assumed to make decisions according to the rational economic model and markets are reasonably efficient, regulations cannot produce large private fuel savings. The behavioral economic model explains not only why such savings do exist but why consumers strongly support fuel economy regulations. The private savings from fuel economy regulations can be large relative to the social benefits of fuel economy and greenhouse gas regulations.
This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.







Notes
- 1.
The sustainability goals are stabilizing global climate change, enhancing energy security and resiliency, eliminating air pollution, and achieving universal access to modern energy services.
- 2.
- 3.
Daniel Kahneman was awarded the Nobel Prize in Economics in 2002 for his work in behavioral economics including Cumulative Prospect Theory and loss aversion. His book cited here, Thinking Fast and Slow, won the National Academies’ Best Book Award for 2012 [31]. Richard Thaler won the 2017 Nobel Prize in Economics for his work in behavioral economics.
- 4.
Weighing losses twice as much as gains is a typical or average loss-averse response. Kahneman [27] cites a range of 1.5 to 2.5, but there is even greater variation among individuals.
- 5.
“Third, by implementing the modular elements of CPT, we can conclude that loss aversion is the major driver of the EE gap. Our results indicate that other elements of CPT, such as probability weighting, have a rather negligible influence. As an exception, however, we find the determination of the reference-point to be very important. Depending on how the EE investment is framed, or perceived by the decision-maker, the EE gap might vanish or be amplified.” [23]
- 6.
Sallee [34] simulated annual fuel costs based on 100,000 random drawings from actual distributions of annual miles, discount rates and the gasoline price forecasts of individual consumers. The estimates varied widely in relation to label values even though uncertainty about actual on-road fuel economy was not included. “This means that even if a fuel economy label explained the lifetime fuel costs accurately for the median driver, that estimate will be too high or too low by $6200, or 50%, on average.” [34], p., 789
- 7.
The measure of variability is insensitive to the discount rate assumed. The analysis is based on annual prices of regular grade gasoline from the EIA October 26, 2018 Monthly Energy Review Table 9.4, converted to 2017 dollars using the FRED GDP price deflator.
- 8.
- 9.
This result is consistent with Dharshing and Hille [45] who found that numeracy and energy literacy were not statistically significantly related to the energy efficiency choices of Swiss households but impulsivity and risk aversion were.
- 10.
The Ford Model T was introduced in 1908.
- 11.
The fifth committee’s work is still in progress and no findings have been issued.
- 12.
Assumes a 6% annual discount rate and a 13-year vehicle lifetime.
- 13.
- 14.
A vehicle’s mass determines the physical work that must be done to accelerate it and to overcome the friction of rolling resistance. Mass is also correlated with size and frontal area, a key determinant of aerodynamic resistance. Finally, apart from a vehicle’s mass, for vehicles with stoichiometric engines, engine size determines how much fuel is consumed per engine revolution.
- 15.
The mathematical representation of loss aversion used is taken from Bernartzi and Thaler [65] and was intended to describe consumers’ behavior in the case of simple win or lose bets. Uncertainties about future fuel savings are far more complex. How best to describe consumers’ decision-making in the face of more complex uncertainties would seem to be an important subject for future research.
- 16.
EUT can include risk aversion. However, risk aversion is different from loss aversion and cannot explain the magnitude of undervaluing implied by loss aversion [66].
- 17.
A common definition of willingness to pay is the maximum amount of money a consumer will give up to obtain a good or avoid a bad [67].
- 18.
A large part of this may be due to different vehicles having different drivers making different kinds of trips.
- 19.
The assumption of independence is a convenient simplification. There is some evidence that the on-road shortfall responds to the price of gasoline [24].
- 20.
The NRC’s high cost function was chosen because it better illustrates situations in which loss-averse consumers would decline fuel economy improvements.
- 21.
A car buyer’s willingness to pay (WTP) for increased fuel economy is calculated based on estimated on-road as opposed to test cycle fuel economy, annual miles driven and the rate at which miles decrease over time, expected vehicle life, expected price of gasoline, and the discount rate for future fuel savings.
- 22.
Taking external costs of fuel consumption into account, the socially optimal mpg would be higher than the privately optimal mpg. On the other hand, the private optimum would include fuel taxes in the price of fuel while the social optimum would not.
- 23.
The automotive market is very competitive even if it is not perfectly competitive. Even assuming oligopolistic supply and Bertrand competition, the shadow price of a binding fuel economy or greenhouse gas emission constraint will induce the adoption of fuel economy improving technologies across all vehicles, except for vehicles that have already adopted all technologies justified by the shadow price.
- 24.
Surveys indicate that US consumers consistently and overwhelmingly approved of fuel economy standards. Typically, 70 to 80% of respondents favored fuel economy standards and raising the standards (5, Table 9.2; 4).
- 25.
References
Papers of particular interest, published recently, have been highlighted as: • Of importance •• Of major importance
- 1.
Global Energy Assessment (GEA). Global Energy Assessment: Toward a Sustainable Future. Laxenburg, Austria: Cambridge University press, Cambridge, UK and New York, NY, USA and the International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis; 2012.
- 2.
Bureau of Transportation Statistics (BTS), 2018. Transportation Statistics Annual Report 2018, p. 7–17, U.S. Department of Transportation, Washington, DC, accessed on 6/3/2019 at https://www.bts.gov/sites/bts.dot.gov/files/docs/browse-statistical-products-and-data/transportation-statistics-annual-reports/TSAR-Full-2018-Web-Final.pdf.
- 3.
U.S. Department of Transportation, Federal Highway Administration (USDOT/FHWA). Highway Statistics 2017, and earlier editions, 2017. Available at https://www.fhwa.dot.gov/policyinformation/statistics.cfm.
- 4.
Greene DL, Welch JG. Impacts of fuel economy improvements on the distribution of income in the US. Energy Policy. 2018;122:528–41.
- 5.
Consumer Reports Survey Group (CRSG). 2017 and 2018. “2018 Automotive Fuel Economy Survey Report” and “2017 Automotive Fuel Economy Survey Report”, provided by Shannon Baker-Brandstetter, Consumers Union, 2018.
- 6.
National Research Council (NRC). Cost, effectiveness, and deployment of fuel economy technologies for light-duty vehicles. Washington, DC: National Academies Press; 2015.
- 7.
Klier T, Linn J. The effect of vehicle fuel economy standards on technology adoption. J Public Econ. 2016;133(C):41–63.
- 8.
Jacobsen M, Benthem V. Vehicle scrappage and gasoline policy. Am Econ Rev. 2015;105(3):1312–38.
- 9.
Jacobsen MR. Evaluating US fuel economy standards in a model with producer and household heterogeneity. Am Econ J Econ Pol. 2013;5(2):148–87.
- 10.
Goulder LH, Jacobsen MR, van Benthem AA. Unintended consequences from nested state & federal regulations: the case of the Pavley greenhouse-gas-per mile limits. J Environ Econ Manag. 2012;63(2):187–207.
- 11.
Klier T, Linn J. New-vehicle characteristics and the cost of the corporate average fuel economy standard. RAND J Econ. 2012;43(1):186–213.
- 12.
Fischer C, Harrington W, Parry I. Do market failures justify tightening corporate average fuel economy (CAFEE) standards? Energy J. 2007;28(4):1–30.
- 13.
Austin D, Dinan T. Clearing the air: the costs and consequences of higher CAFE standards and increased gasoline taxes. J Environ Econ Manag. 2005;50(3):562–82.
- 14.
West SE, Williams RC. The cost of reducing gasoline consumption. Am Econ Rev. 2005;95(2):294–9.
- 15.
Kleit AN. Impacts of long-range increases in the fuel economy (CAFE) standard. Econ Inq. 2004;42(2):279–94.
- 16.
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (USEPA). Regulatory impact analysis: final rulemaking for 2017–2025 light-duty vehicle greenhouse gas emission standards and corporate average fuel economy standards. EPA-420-R-12-016, 2012. Available at https://nepis.epa.gov/Exe/ZyPDF.cgi/P100EZI1.PDF?Dockey=P100EZI1.PDF .
- 17.
National Research Council (NRC). Automotive fuel economy: how far can we go? Report of the committee on automobile and light truck fuel economy. Washington, DC: National Academy Press; 1992.
- 18.
National Research Council (NRC). Effectiveness and impact of corporate average fuel economy (CAFE) standards, Report of the Committee. Washington: National Academy Press; 2002. p. 2002.
- 19.
National Research Council (NRC). Assessment of fuel economy technologies for light-duty vehicles, report of the committee on the assessment of technologies for improving light-duty vehicle fuel economy. Washington, D.C.: National Academies Press; 2011.
- 20.
Gerarden TD, Newell RG, Stavins RN, Stowe RC. An assessment of the energy-efficiency gap and its implications for climate-change policy, working paper 20905. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of economic research; 2015.
- 21.
Gillingham K, Palmer K. Bridging the energy efficiency gap: policy insights from economic theory and empirical evidence. Rev Environ Econ Policy. 2014;8(1):18–38.
- 22.
Heutel G. Prospect theory and energy efficiency, NBER working paper 23692. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of economic research; 2017.
- 23.
Häckel B, Pfosser S, Tränkler T. Explaining the energy efficiency gap – expected utility theory versus cumulative prospect theory. Energy Policy. 2017;111:414–26.
- 24.
Greene DL. Uncertainty, loss aversion and markets for energy efficiency. Energy Econ. 2011;33:608–16.
- 25.
Starmer C. Developments in non-expected utility theory: the hunt for a descriptive theory of choice under risk. J Econ Lit. 2000;38:332–82.
- 26.
Dellavigna S. Psychology and economics: evidence from the field. J Econ Lit. 2009;47(2):315–72.
- 27.
Kahneman D. Thinking fast and slow. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux; 2011.
- 28.
Thaler RH. Misbehaving: the making of behavioral economics. New York: W.W. Norton & Company; 2015.
- 29.
Novemsky N, Kahneman D. The boundaries of loss aversion. J Market Res. 2005;XLII:119–28.
- 30.
Ert E, Erev I. On the descriptive value of loss aversion in decisions under risk: six clarifications. Judgm Decis Mak. 2013;8(3):214–35.
- 31.
National Academies. Daniel Kahneman’s thinking, fast and slow wins best book award from academies, 2012. Accessed on 10/17/2018 at http://www8.nationalacademies.org/onpinews/newsitem.aspx?RecordID=09132012.
- 32.
Tom SM, Fox CR, Trepel C, Poldrack RA. The neural basis of decision-making under risk. Science. 2007;315:515–8.
- 33.
Kahneman D, Tversky A. Prospect theory: an analysis of decision making under risk. Econometrica. 1979;47:263–91.
- 34.
Sallee JM. Rational inattention and energy efficiency. J Law Econ. 2014;57(3):781–820.
- 35•
Greene DL, Khattak AJ, Liu J, Wang X, Hopson JL, Goeltz R. What is the evidence concerning the gap between on-road and Environmental Protection Agency fuel economy ratings? Transport Policy. 2017;53:146–60. This paper summarizes evidence from four U.S. nationwide random sample surveys that framed fuel economy choices as risky bets. The results were as predicted by the behavioral economic principle of loss aversion and were also consistent with the stated beliefs of automobile manufacturers.
- 36.
Hamilton JD. Understanding crude oil prices. Energy J. 2009;30(2):179–206.
- 37.
Energy Information Administration (EIA). Gasoline explained: gasoline price fluctuations, 2018. Available at https://wwweiagov/energyexplained/indexphp?page=gasoline_fluctuations as of November 14, 2018.
- 38.
Lin Z, Greene DL. Predicting individual on-road fuel economy using simple consumer and vehicle attributes, SAE Technical Paper Series No. 11SDP-0014. Warrendale, PA: Society of Automotive Engineers; 2011.
- 39.
Tversky A, Kahneman D. The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice. Science. 1981;211(4481):453–8.
- 40.
Gal D, Rucker DD. The loss of loss aversion: will it loom larger than its gain. J Consum Psychol. 2018;28(3):497–516.
- 41.
Erev I, Ert E, Plonsky O, Cohen D, Cohen O. From anomalies to forecasts: toward a descriptive model of decisions under risk, under ambiguity, and from experience. Psychol Rev. 2017;124(4):369–409.
- 42.
Walsworth J. Average age of vehicles on road hits 11.3 years, Automotive News, 2016. 11/22/16 accessed on 8/29/18 at http://www.autonews.com/article/20161122/RETAIL05/161129973/average-age-of-vehicles-on-road-hits-11.6-years.
- 43.
Statista. Average length of vehicle ownership in the United States in 2006 and 2016, by vehicle type (in months). 2018, accessed on 8/29/18 at https://www.statista.com/statistics/581017/average-length-of-vehicle-ownership-in-the-united-states-by-vehicle-type/.
- 44•
Turrentine TS, Kurani KS. Car buyers and fuel economy? Energy Policy. 2007;35:1213–23. This descriptive investigation of the car purchase decisions of households in California found that the rational economic model was not employed by any household when making decisions about fuel economy. Instead, consumers’ fuel economy decisions were overwhelmingly intuitive or based on simple rules.
- 45.
Dharshing S, Hille SL. The energy paradox revisted: analyzing the role of individual differences and framing effects in information perception. J Consum Policy. 2017;40:485–508.
- 46.
Leard B. Consumer inattention and the demand for vehicle fuel cost savings. J Choice Model. 2018;29:1–16.
- 47.
Greene DL, Evans DH, Hiestand J. Survey evidence on the willingness of U.S. consumers to pay for automotive fuel economy. Energy Policy. 2013;61:1539–50.
- 48•
Greene DL, DeCicco JM. Engineering-economic analyses of automotive fuel economy potential in the United States. Annu Rev Energ Environ. 2000;25:477–536. This paper finds that for consumers’ choices among energy efficiency options, the important aspects of cumulative prospect theory are loss aversion and reference dependence.
- 49.
Greene DL. How consumers value fuel economy: a literature review, EPA-420-R-10-008, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, 2010.
- 50.
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (USEPA). Consumer willingness to pay for vehicle attributes: what is the current state of knowledge? Ann Arbor, MI: EPA-420-R-18-016, Assessment and Standards Division, Office of Transportation and Air Quality, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency; 2018.
- 51.
Greene DL, Hossain A, Hofmann J, Helfand G, Beach R. Consumer willingness to pay for vehicle attributes: what do we know? Transport Res A. 2018;118:258–79.
- 52•
Helfand G, Wolverton A. Evaluating consumer response to fuel economy: a review of the literature. Int Rev Environ Resour Econ. 2011;5(2):103–46. The experiments analyzed in this paper show that loss aversion can explain consumers’ choices among energy efficiency options and that the private savings from cost-effective increases in energy efficiency can exceed the value of reduced externalities.
- 53.
Allcott H, Wozny N. Gasoline prices, fuel economy and the energy paradox. Rev Econ Stat. 2014;XCVI(5):779–95.
- 54.
Anderson ST, Kellogg R, Sallee JM. What do consumers believe about future gasoline prices? J Environ Econ Manag. 2013;66(3):383–403.
- 55.
Sallee JM, West SE, Fan W. Do consumers recognize the value of fuel economy? Evidence from used car prices and gasoline price fluctuations. J Public Econ. 2016;135:61–73.
- 56.
U.S. Department of Transportation, National Highway Traffic Safety Administration (USDOT NHTSA). Vehicle survivability and travel mileage schedules, Technical Report DOT HS 809 952, National Center for Statistics and Analysis, U.S. Department of Transportation, 2006.
- 57.
Busse MR, Knittel CR, Zettelmeyer F. Are consumers myopic? Evidence from new and used car purchases. Am Econ Rev. 2013;103(1):220–56.
- 58.
Bento AM, Roth K, Zuo Y. Vehicle lifetime trends and scrappage behavior in the U.S. Used Car Market, UCLA. 2016, available at file:///C:/Users/HP%20USER/Desktop/Reviews/BentoetalFuelEconScrappage_18Jan2016.pdf.
- 59.
Leard B, Linn J, Zhou YC. How much do consumers value fuel economy and performance?, RFF report. Washington, D.C., June: Resources for the Future; 2017.
- 60.
Pagerit S, Sharer P, Rousseau A. Fuel economy sensitivity to vehicle mass for advanced vehicle powertrains. Warrendale, PA: SAE-2006-01-0665, Society of Automotive Engineers; 2006.
- 61.
Knittel CR. Automobiles on steroids: product attribute trade-offs and technological progress in the automobile sector. Am Econ Rev. 2012;101:3368–99.
- 62.
Larrick RP, Soll JB. The MPG illusion. Science. 2008;320:1593–4.
- 63.
Schoemaker PJH. The expected utility model: its variants, purposes, evidence and limitations. J Econ Literature. 1982;XX:529–63.
- 64.
Katsikopolous KV. Bounded rationality: the two cultures. J Econ Methodol. 2014;21(4):361–74.
- 65.
Bernartzi S, Thaler R. Myopic loss aversion and the equity premium puzzle. Q J Econ. 1995;110:73–92.
- 66.
Rabin M. Risk aversion and expected utility theory: a calibration theorem. Econometrica. 2003;68:1281–92.
- 67.
Varian H. Microeconomic analysis. New York: W.W. Norton & Co., Inc.; 1992.
- 68.
Wali B, Greene DL, Khattak AJ, Liu J. Analyzing within garage fuel economy gaps to support vehicle purchasing decisions–a copula-based modeling & forecasting approach. Transp Res D. 2018;63:186–208.
- 69.
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (FRED). Finance rate on consumer installment loans at commercial banks, New Autos 48 and 60 month loans. 2019, accessed on 6/7/2019 at https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/TERMCBAUTO48NS and https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/RIFLPBCIANM60NM.
- 70.
U.S. Department of Transportation, Federal Highway Administration (USDOT/FHWA). National Household Travel Survey 2017, 2018. Available at https://nhts.ornl.gov/.
- 71.
Davis SC, Williams SE, Boundy RG. Transportation energy data book: edition 36. ORNL/TM-2017/513-R2. Oak Ridge, TN: Oak Ridge National Laboratory; 2018. Available at https://cta.ornl.gov/ as of August 2018
- 72.
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (USEPA). Light-duty automotive technology, Carbon Dioxide Emissions, and Fuel Economy Trends: 1975 Through 2017, EPA-420-R-18-001, Ch. 5, section B, pp. 57-59, EPA-420-R-18-001, 2017.
- 73.
U.S. Department of Transportation, National Highway Traffic Safety Administration, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (USDOT, USEPA), 2018. Notice of proposed rulemaking (NPRM): The safer affordable fuel-efficient (SAFE) vehicles rule for model year 2021–2026 passenger cars and light trucks, 2018b. Available at https://www.federalregister.gov/documents/2018/08/24/2018-18418/the-safer-affordable-fuel-efficient-safe-vehicles-rule-for-model-years-2021-2026-passenger-cars-and.
- 74.
U.S. Department of Transportation, National Highway Traffic Safety Administration (USDOT, NHTSA). Preliminary regulatory impact analysis (PRIA): The safer affordable fuel-efficient (SAFE) vehicles rule for model year 2021–2026 passenger cars and light trucks, 2018a. Available at https://www.nhtsa.gov/sites/nhtsa.dot.gov/files/documents/ld-cafe-co2-nhtsa-2127-al76-epa-pria-180823.pdf.
- 75.
Tsvetanov T, Segerson K. Re-evaluating the role of energy efficiency standards: a behavioral economics approach. J Environ Econ Manag. 2013;66:347–63.
- 76.
Bernheim BD. The good the bad and the ugly: a unified approach to behavioral welfare economics. J Benefit-cost Anal. 2016;7(1):12–68.
- 77.
Kahneman D, Sugden R. Experienced utility as a standard of policy evaluation. Environ Resour Econ. 2005;31:161–81.
- 78.
Allcott H, Mullainathan S, Taubinsky D. Energy policy with externalities and internalities. J Public Econ. 2014;112:72–88.
- 79.
Greene DL, Patterson PD, Singh M, Li J. Feebates, rebates and gas-guzzler taxes: a study of incentives for increased fuel economy. Energy Policy. 2005;33(6):721–827.
- 80.
Liu C, Greene DL, Bunch DS. Vehicle manufacturer technology adoption and pricing strategies under fuel economy/emissions standards and Feebates. Energy J. 2014;35(3):71–89.
Author information
Affiliations
Corresponding author
Ethics declarations
Conflict of Interest
David L. Greene declares that he has no conflict of interest.
Human and Animal Rights and Informed Consent
This article does not contain any studies with human or animal subjects performed by any of the authors.
Additional information
Publisher’s Note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
This article is part of the Topical Collection on Transportation
The author is a Senior Fellow of the Howard H. Baker, Jr. Center for Public Policy and a Research Professor of Civil and Environmental Engineering at the University of Tennessee. The views expressed in this report are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect those of the institutions with which he is associated.
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Greene, D.L. Implications of Behavioral Economics for the Costs and Benefits of Fuel Economy Standards. Curr Sustainable Renewable Energy Rep 6, 177–192 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40518-019-00134-3
Published:
Issue Date:
Keywords
- Fuel economy standards
- Loss aversion
- Energy-efficiency gap
- Greenhouse gas regulations
- Behavioral economics
- Cost/benefit analysis