Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Rethinking the Two-Body Problem: The Segregation of Women Into Geographically Dispersed Occupations

  • Published:
Demography

Abstract

Empirical research on the family cites the tendency for couples to relocate for husbands’ careers as evidence against the gender neutrality of household economic decisions. For these studies, occupational segregation is a concern because occupations are not random by sex and mobility is not random by occupation. I find that the tendency for households to relocate for husbands’ careers is better explained by the segregation of women into geographically dispersed occupations rather than by the direct prioritization of men’s careers. Among never-married workers, women relocate for work less often than men, and the gender effect disappears after occupational segregation is accounted for. Although most two-earner families feature husbands in geographically clustered jobs involving frequent relocation for work, families are no less likely to relocate for work when it belongs to the wife. I conclude that future research in household mobility should treat occupational segregation occurring prior to marriage rather than gender bias within married couples as the primary explanation for the prioritization of husbands’ careers in household mobility decisions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The study of the segregation of women into low-paying jobs within firms is a familiar application of this approach; fine-grained controls reduce and virtually eliminate the estimated effect of sex (see, for example, Petersen and Morgan 1995 or Reskin and Bielby 2005). However, because relocations for work are rare, introducing occupational fixed effects makes tests very weak. Including a linear term for clustering instead maintains the statistical power of the test while tying results to the specific theoretical construct provided by clustering.

  2. Available online (http://www.usa.ipums.org). See Ruggles et al. (2010).

  3. The 2000 PUMS distinguishes 337 occupations by (up to) a six-digit SOC code. By exploiting the hierarchical nature of SOC codes, it is easy to show that aggregating occupations (for example, to three-digit categories) reduces the magnitude of the effects, suggesting potential aggregation bias. Reskin (1993:243) also noted this bias: “. . . ‘college and university teacher’ includes someone teaching night classes on repairing office machines at Parkland Community College as well as a distinguished professor of mathematics at Harvard.” Likewise, segregation into highly mobile subspecialties within occupations would not be captured by aggregate measures like SOC codes. The resulting measurement error (in the independent variable) is expected to cause attenuation bias, reducing the magnitude of the estimated coefficients and increasing the standard errors.

  4. The March CPS features six-digit SOC codes beginning in 2003. Unlike the census or PSID, it asks relocating households to report the primary reason for relocating in the prior year, including “for work or job transfer.” Only 10 % of relocations are for work, and geographic flexibility may lead workers to relocate for reasons other than work, confounding estimates that use observed relocations for all reasons. The March CPS also has much greater statistical power than the PSID. Data are available on the IPUMS website (http://www.cps.ipums.org) (see Ruggles et al. 2010).

  5. Unfortunately, although the CPS reports the principal reason for household relocations, its sample size is far too small to estimate relocation likelihoods by occupation.

  6. “Physicists and astronomers” are treated as distinct from “postsecondary teachers” by the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics.

  7. To sign the omitted variable bias posed by the correlation between sex and occupational clustering, I examine pairwise correlations between a female dummy variable, a worker’s occupational clustering score, and an indicator variable denoting that the worker relocates for work. The correlation between the female dummy variable and the clustering score is negative (Hypothesis 1A), and the correlation between the clustering score and relocation for work is positive (Hypothesis 1B), both with p < .01. Therefore, without controlling for clustering, the raw correlation between female and relocation will be biased downward. These correlations are each robust and significant in all nine explored specifications: the full sample, by age less than 35, for never-married and married workers, and by college education (i.e., 1 + 23). Although correlations were strongest among the young and college educated, this check suggests that the OVB very broadly leads to downwardly biased estimates of the independent effect of sex on relocation for work.

  8. Primary reason for relocation is a self-reported variable, and I also examine relocation reported for reasons other than work (results are available upon request). As shown in Table 2, treating “all relocations” as the dependent variable has the following effects: the magnitude of all coefficients is reduced, the coefficient for clustering remains a statistically significant predictor of relocations, and the coefficient for the female variable loses significance in columns 3 and 7. Treating relocations primarily “for family” as the dependent variable has the following effects: the coefficient on clustering loses significance, and the coefficient for the female variable rises. I interpret results to suggest that never-married women are more likely than men to cite family as the primary reason why they relocate, and the geographic clustering of a job is a better predictor of relocations that households report are primarily “for work.”

  9. Among dual-earner couples, 5.09 % of men and women have the same occupation. To avoid bias, the terms for maximal clustering is zero for both spouses when occupations match. These couples are significantly more likely to relocate for work than spouses where the occupations do not match (23.9 %, with a standard error of 9.3 %). One possibility is that work relocations are easier when the husband and wife have the same occupation.

  10. There are also exceptions to the generalization that engineering and technical occupations are geographically clustered; for example, civil engineers, accountants, and auditors are technical occupations, and they are dispersed. They also have rapidly absorbed highly educated women.

  11. This approach would also build on research on the migration of college-educated couples into large metropolitan areas that may be amenable to supporting two careers (see, e.g., Costa and Kahn 2000).

References

  • Acker, J. (1990). Hierarchies, jobs, bodies: A theory of gendered organizations. Gender and Society, 4, 139–158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anker, R. (1997). Theories of occupational segregation by sex: An overview. International Labour Review, 136, 129–155.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bailey, A., & Cooke, T. (1998). Family migration and employment: The importance of migration history and gender. International Regional Science Review, 21, 99–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Battu, H., Seaman, P., & Sloane, P. (1998). Are married women spatially constrained? A test of gender differentials in labour market outcomes (ERSA Conference Paper). Vienna, Austria: European Regional Science Association. Retrieved from http://www.ersa.org

  • Becker, P., & Moen, P. (1999). Scaling back: Dual-earner couples’ work-family strategies. Journal of Marriage and the Family, 61, 995–1007.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benson, A. (Forthcoming). A theory of dual job search and sex-based occupational clustering. Industrial Relations.

  • Bielby, D., & Bielby, W. (1992). I will follow him: Family ties, gender-role beliefs, and reluctance to relocate for a better job. American Journal of Sociology, 97, 1241–1267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blau, F., & Ferber, M. (1991). Career plans and expectations of young women and men: The earnings gap and labor force participation. Journal of Human Resources, 26, 581–607.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyle, P., Cooke, T., Halfacree, K., & Smith, D. (2001). A cross-national comparison of the impact of family migration on women’s employment status. Demography, 38, 201–213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandén, M., & Ström, S. (2013). Couples’ education and regional mobility—The importance of occupation, income, and gender. Population, Space and Place, 19, 522–536.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brewster, K., & Padavic, I. (2004). Change in gender-ideology, 1977–1996: The contributions of intracohort change and population turnover. Journal of Marriage and Family, 62, 477–487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ciabattari, T. (2001). Changes in men’s conservative gender ideologies. Gender and Society, 15, 574–591.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, W. A. V., & Huang, Y. (2006). Balancing move and work: Women’s labour market exits and entries after family migration. Population, Space and Place, 12, 31–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, P., & Huffman, M. (2003). Individuals, jobs, and labor markets: The devaluation of women’s work. American Journal of Sociology, 68, 443–463.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Compton, J., & Pollak, R. A. (2007). Why are power couples increasingly concentrated in large metropolitan areas? Journal of Labor Economics, 25, 475–512.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooke, T. (2003). Family migration and the relative earnings of husbands and wives. Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 93, 338–349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costa, D. L., & Kahn, M. E. (2000). Power couples: Changes in the locational choice of the college educated, 1940–1990. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, 1287–1315.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daymont, T. N., & Andrisani, P. J. (1984). Job preferences, college major, and the gender gap in earnings. Journal of Human Resources, 19, 408–428.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Echevarria, C., & Merlo, A. (1999). Gender differences in education in a dynamic household bargaining model. International Economic Review, 40, 265–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ellison, G., & Glaeser, E. L. (1997). Geographic concentration in U.S. manufacturing industries: A dartboard approach. Journal of Political Economy, 105, 889–927.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engineer, M., & Welling, L. (1998). Human capital, true love, and gender roles: Is sex destiny? Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 40(2), 155–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, C. F. (1990). Deceptive distinctions: Sex, gender, and the social order. Binghampton, NY: Vail-Ballou Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez, R., & Su, C. (2004). Space in the study of labor markets. Annual Review of Sociology, 30, 545–569.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friede Westring, A., & Ryan, A. M. (2011). Anticipated work-family conflict: A construct investigation. Journal of Vocational Behavior, 79, 596–610.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gill, L., & Haurin, D. (2002). Wherever he may go: How wives affect their husband’s career decisions. Social Science Research, 27, 264–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hadfield, G. (1999). A coordination model of the sexual division of labor. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 40, 125–153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanson, S., & Pratt, G. (1995). Gender, work, and space. New York, NY: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Helppie, B., & Murray-Close, M. (2010). Moving out or moving up? New economists sacrifice job opportunities for proximity to significant others—and vice versa (Working paper). Retrieved from http://www-personal.umich.edu/~Ebhelppie/helppie_ch2.pdf

  • Jacobsen, J., & Levin, L. (2000). The effects of internal migration on the relative economic status of women and men. Journal of Socio-Economics, 29, 291–304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kanter, R. M. (1977). Men and women of the corporation. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Long, L. (1974). Women’s labor force participation and the residential mobility of families. Social Forces, 52, 342–348.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markham, W., & Pleck, J. (1986). Sex and willingness to move for occupational advancement: Some national results. Sociological Quarterly, 27, 121–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKinnish, T. (2008). Spousal mobility and earnings. Demography, 45, 829–849.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McNeil, L., & Sher, M. (2008). Dual-science career couples: Survey results. Physics Today, 52(7), 32–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mincer, J. (1978). Family migration decisions. Journal of Political Economy, 86, 749–773.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nivalainen, S. (2005). Interregional migration and post-move employment in two-earner families: Evidence from Finland. Regional Studies, 39, 891–907.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Noe, R., Steffy, B., & Barber, A. (1988). An investigation of the factor influencing employees’ willingness to accept mobility opportunities. Personnel Psychology, 41, 559–580.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostroff, C., & Clark, M. (2001). Maintaining an internal market: Antecedents of willingness to change jobs. Journal of Vocational Behavior, 59, 425–453.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Petersen, T., & Morgan, L. (1995). Separate and unequal: Occupation-establishment sex segregation and the gender wage gap. American Journal of Sociology, 101, 329–365.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pixley, J. (2008). Life course patterns of career-prioritizing decisions and occupational attainment in dual-earner couples. Work and Occupations, 35(2), 127–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pixley, J., & Moen, P. (2003). It’s about time: Couples and careers. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reskin, B. (1993). Sex segregation in the workplace. Annual Review of Sociology, 19, 241–270.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reskin, B., & Bielby, D. (2005). A sociological perspective on gender and career outcomes. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 191, 71–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ressner, U. (1987). The hidden hierarchy: Democracy and equal opportunities. Gower, UK: Aldershot.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ruggles, S., Alexander, T., Genadek, K., Goeken, R., Schroeder, M. B., & Sobek, M. (2010). Integrated public use microdata series: Version 5.0 [Machine-readable database]. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota.

  • Sandell, S. (1977). Women and the economics of family migration. Review of Economics and Statistics, 59, 406–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shauman, K. (2010). Gender asymmetry in family migration: Occupational inequality or interspousal comparative advantage? Journal of Marriage and Family, 72, 375–392.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shauman, K., & Noonan, M. (2007). Family migration and labor force outcomes: Sex differences in occupational context. Social Forces, 85, 1735–1764.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shihadeh, E. (1991). The prevalence of husband-centered migration: Employment consequences for married mothers. Journal of Marriage and the Family, 53, 432–444.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, R., & Landis, J. (1989). Women’s and men’s attitudes about a woman’s place and role. Public Opinion Quarterly, 53, 265–276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sorenson, O., & Dahl, M. (2011). Geography, joint choices, and the reproduction of gender inequality (Working paper). Retrieved from http://ssrn.com/abstract=1968440

  • Swain, L. L., & Garasky, S. (2007). Migration decisions of dual-earner families: An application of multilevel modeling. Journal of Family and Economic Issues, 28, 151–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Turban, D., Campion, J., & Eyring, A. (1992). Factors relating to relocation decisions of research and development employees. Journal of Vocational Behavior, 41, 183–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zvonkovic, A., Greaves, K., Schmiege, C., & Hall, L. (1996). The marital construction of gender through work and family decisions: A qualitative analysis. Journal of Marriage and the Family, 58, 91–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I thank Dan Fehder, Roberto Fernandez, Stephanie Hurder, Erin Kelly, George Lan, Colleen Manchester, Matt Marx, Paul Osterman, Gina Rumore, workshop participants at MIT and the Minnesota Population Center, IWER Workshop participants, and MPC Workshop participants for their helpful feedback. I also gratefully acknowledge support from the Minnesota Population Center (5R24HD041023). Replication materials are available upon request. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alan Benson.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Benson, A. Rethinking the Two-Body Problem: The Segregation of Women Into Geographically Dispersed Occupations. Demography 51, 1619–1639 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s13524-014-0324-7

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s13524-014-0324-7

Keywords

Navigation