In this section, we introduce a pension design that avoids the two core guarantees inherent in the classical pension products: guaranteed rate of interest and guaranteed mortality rates. Our proposed design, we call it “maximal with-profit”, offers a new understanding of security through smoothing corridors in both accumulation and retirement phases and additional safety layers in case of adverse financial conditions.
We use a similar idea to the one suggested in [5], where the so-called annuity pools are discussed. Annuity pools guarantee the insured solely a lifelong pension that is feasible for the collective of pensioners under the actual interest and actually expected development of the mortality rates. In equidistant intervals, for instance yearly, the pension amount can be adjusted if necessary (both upward and downward modifications are possible). Further, annuity pools are using the idea of a tontine: a redistribution of assets from those who die before average to those who live longer. The advantages for the insurer are obvious: a better solvency position or reduced liabilities. The feedback strategy and the absence of the safety margins lead to a higher initial pension which represents the biggest advantage of such a construction from the pensioner’s standpoint. However, if life expectancy of the customers increases on average more than calculated, pensions will decrease.
Our proposed design goes beyond the annuity pools and unit-linked (unitised with-profit) schemes. The idea is to replace traditional guarantees with low volatility, mainly achieved by collective smoothing algorithms and an adequate asset management. Waiving traditional guarantees allows a more return-oriented asset management and as a consequence higher expected returns for the policyholder and reduced liabilities for the employer. In order to avoid any ambiguities, we would like to emphasise that the choice of funds and asset management lies completely in the hands of insurance companies.
First of all, we divide our considerations on the time scale into two parts, as illustrated in Fig. 1. The first time interval lasts from the inception of a contract to the retirement point—the accumulation phase, the second interval, is the retirement phase which ends upon death of the insured person.Footnote 1
At the retirement point, depending on regulations in place, the product design might stipulate the payment of the accumulated amount as a lump sum, i.e. the contract ends at the retirement point. However, in many countries a transition to the retirement phase is obligatory.
The overall target of the maximal with-profit is twofold: to maximise the total saved amount (alternatively the first pension or the discounted pension payments expected at the retirement point) and to keep the pension evolution inside a corridor, mitigating the risk of a decrease. With this in mind, our model uses the corridor volatility smoothing method, collective mechanisms and financial safety layers.
At the retirement point, if the considered product allows for the retirement phase, we transfer the saved amount into the new collective fund and calculate the first premium accordingly. It is clear, the higher the savings for a concrete individual are the higher will be her/his first (initial) pension. The smoothing mechanism in the retirement phase again consists of interaction between two layers: the collective fund and an additional safety layer. This allows to increase the pensions if the underlying funds go up and prevents, to some extent, decreasing the pensions if the funds go down. In the extreme case that the actual market situation becomes not manageable for the insurance company and the safety layer is empty, the pensions would need to be reduced. See Example 3 below for a simulation of such a situation.
In the next subsections we explain with more detail a corridor smoothing method that can be applied both in the saving and in the retirement phases, the redistribution index that calculates a fair share of the accumulated collective wealth for the individual, the additional safety layer, the characteristics of the retirement phase and the optimisation targets.
Corridor smoothing in the saving phase
We consider the corridor smoothing procedure from the point of view of an insurance company. Assume for simplicity that the insurance company has chosen two funds, say F and H. The fund F is supposed to be more risky and is aimed at having higher returns while H is more conservative and is used mainly to reduce volatility of the fund F. However, it is possible to choose \(F=H\). Since the smoothing procedure will be applied on two funds through exchange of units, long-term investments and even illiquid product types are allowed. The asset management of the insurance company controls the structure and the evolution of both funds.
We design an individual pension contract as follows. The net premia are divided, under an agreed percentage, into the individual and the collective part. The individual part is invested into the fund F, the collective part is invested into H. Thus, all insured are paying a part of their premia into the joint collective account (Collective account 1 in Fig. 1), and the remaining part into their individual accounts. For products containing a retirement phase, the amount saved in the individual accounts plus a percentage of the collective fund are transferred to the collective account in the retirement phase (Collective account 2 in Fig. 1) at the retirement age of the insured. Apart from this transfer, the pool of contributions and the pool of pensions are independent in the sense that there is no interaction like for instance in the PAYG scheme.
Assume for the moment that there are no premium payments, surrender or deaths in the considered periods. Let \(F_0\) be the value of an individual fund at time zero. Let further k be a fixed real number from the interval [0, 100]. The parameter k determines a volatility smoothing corridor in the following sense. The upward and downward movements of the individual fund F are observed at discrete time points. If the current value of the fund compared to the previous observation lies outside the interval \([100\%-k\%,100\%+k\%]\) it has to be adjusted as explained below. If after a certain period of time, say after a year, the fund F performs \(k\%\) worse than the year before, a certain part, say \(q\%\), of the deficit will be transferred from the collective account into the individual one. If the fund F performs \(k\%\) better, a percentage of the excess, say \(p\%\) will be transferred into the collective account. An example is given in Fig. 2. The same procedure will be repeated after the next year. However, the reference value will be \(F_1\). Thus, the collective account helps to keep the evolution of the individual account inside the corridor. For the case that the collective account can become empty an additional safety layer can be introduced to the model. Note that all contracts in one scheme will use the same parameters q and p. The parameter k can be the same for all contributors or be chosen individually.
Example 1
Let us fix \(k=10\), \(p=25\) and \(q=50\) by the start of the contract. A possible evolution of the fund F over 3 years is shown in Fig. 2. In this scenario, we see that if the initial value \(F_0=0.5\) the value after one year is \(F_1=0.25\). Since the decrease of \(50\%\) exceeds the given boundary of \(10\%\), the individual fund gets capital from the collective fund in the amount of \(q\%=50\%\) of the loss exceeding the lower corridor boundary: \(F_0\frac{100-k}{100}-F_1\). Thus, the new value of the fund F at time 1, we denote it by \(F_1^{\mathrm{new}}\), is
$$\begin{aligned} F_1^{\mathrm{new}}=F_1+\frac{q}{100}\Big (\frac{100-k}{100}F_0-F_1\Big )=0.25+0.5\big (0.9\cdot 0.5-0.25\big )=0.35. \end{aligned}$$
We start the next period with the initial value \(F_1^{new}=0.35\). Then, as shown in Fig. 3, the value of the fund F at time 2 is given by 0.7. Since the increase is more than \(10\%\), the individual fund transfers \(p\%=25\%\) of the excess to the collective account. The new value of the fund after the application of the smoothing strategy at time 2 is given by
$$\begin{aligned} F_2^{\mathrm{new}}=0.7-\frac{p}{100}\Big (0.7-\frac{100+k}{100}F_1^{\mathrm{new}}\Big )=0.7-0.25\Big (0.7-1.1\cdot 0.35\Big )=0.62125\;. \end{aligned}$$
And finally, starting with initial value 0.62125 we end up with 0.6 in year 3. The decrease stays inside the corridor and it is not needed to modify the process.
Please note that the paths in both Figs. 2 and 3 are identical in the time period [0, 1] and differ afterwards. This is due to the fact that by changing the initial value also the evolution of the process might change. The high values of the fund F during the period [2, 3] are not taken into consideration because the smoothing strategy is assumed to be applied yearly. The frequency of the adjustments can be modified. However, the following aspects have to be taken into account. Shorter time intervals will increase the impact of the volatility and consequently require more frequent adjustments. On the one hand, it will increase the transaction costs. On the other hand, using long-term or illiquid assets would not even allow for very frequent adjustments. \(\;\;\;\;\;\;\blacksquare\)
In general, it must be noted that applying the smoothing on the neighbouring observation points might ignore a continuous decrease of the fund without the possibility to react in the framework of the strategy described above. For instance for \(k=10\) the fund might develop like shown in Fig. 4: the fund value at any observation point is smaller than in the previous year but the decrease is less than \(k\%=10\%\), i.e. no actions are allowed. A solution could be to always compare the values of the fund with the initial value at time zero. In this case, given the situation in Fig. 4, already after the 2nd year (decrease of \(23\%\) compared to the initial value of 0.5) the considered individual fund gets financial help from the collective fund. Another possibility to improve the situation would be to apply a feedback strategy for k.
Individual smoothing: better or not?
From an individual point of view, it is more desirable that following the development of the fund, a feedback strategy governing/changing the value of k, say yearly, would be preferred. This might yield more chances for the individual to maximise the saved amount and consequently the value of pensions than a constant k chosen at the beginning of the contract. The running management expenses will not increase considerably. Thus, one can maximise the whole saved amount at the time of retirement (given the insured person stays alive and will not surrender) over all \(k\in [0,100]\) to be chosen at the adjustment times post-smoothing. Due to different premium payment behaviour and different run-time of the contracts, it would make sense to determine the boundary k individually for each contract. However, depending on the stipulated help procedure from the collective account and/or from the third layer, the individual accounts might become dependent, i.e. the optimal choice of the level k will depend on the choices made for other individuals in the pool of insured. Multivariate optimisation problems with dependent variables are not easy tasks to handle. For the sake of transparency, insurance companies and regulating authorities might want to simplify the calculation procedures and require the same level k for all individual contracts. This method can be justified from the mathematical point of view by applying the mean-field game theory. If the pool of insured is large enough and every contractor has the same risk-averseness, it can be shown that the best choice of k for each contract depends just on the total amount saved in all individual accounts and the collective amount, i.e. the same k is used for everyone.
Products with retirement phase
For products with a retirement phase, one can think about the first pension as a target to optimise. By signing of the contract, an insurance company can agree to update the insured not only on the development of the fund but also on the first expected pension under the current market situation and mortality rates. In this case one would need an (exogenously given, see Sect. 2.6) condition specifying the first pension in dependence of the savings of a concrete individual. Such a condition might be a parameter gained from the pool of pensioners which is up to the transfer of savings at the transition point independent of the pool of active contributors as one can see in Fig. 1.
Redistribution index
It is important to give a cohort that leaves the saving phase a fair share of the accumulated collective wealth, Collective account 1 in Fig. 1. A simple solution to obtain an indicator would be to consider the relation of the total premia paid by the individual to the total premia paid by all individuals in the accumulation phase. Applying this reference number to the current collective fund value would yield the desired amount.
However, this solution does not take into account the possibility of late lump sum premium payments close to the retirement point. Imagine the following situation. Person 1 and Person 2 are paying premia yearly to the amount of \(P_1\) and \(P_2\) correspondingly with \(P_1<P_2\). After 30 years and one year before the retirement, Person 1 decides to pay \(30(P_2-P_1)\) as a lump sum premium. It means the total premium amount of the Persons 1 and 2 are equal and so is their share on the collective capital. If the collective fund has been increasing in the recent years, Person 1 is making an arbitrage by participating in gains to the same percentage as Person 2. Also, this situation contradicts the core idea of our product design: partially collective risk sharing. The risk is totally with Person 2, but the gains are equally distributed between Persons 1 and 2.
A possible solution would be to put weights on account values in different time intervals: the earlier a value the higher the weight. An example is provided by the calculation procedures in redistribution of hidden reserves (the difference between market and book value of assets) in Germany. There, the late payments are penalised so that a situation described above is not possible. For further examples of redistribution procedures see for instance [3, 8, 13] and references therein.
Another possibility to define a redistribution index is to use the total amount of shares purchased for an individual from her/his contributions into the collective account divided by the total number of shares in the collective account. In the worst case scenario, when the asset prices fall sharply this could be leveraged by policyholders through a large contribution initiating an acquisition of a substantial amount of shares at cheap prices. However, one expects that the asset prices increase in expectation because otherwise entering or staying in the scheme would not be beneficial to the individuals. Thus, usually those who pay in later face the risk of having a lesser amount of shares at the end of the contribution phase compared to those who have been paying in regularly.
Since the redistribution index plays a crucial role in the determination of the first pension, it needs a detailed discussion concerning the desired properties and possible outcomes. However, such a discussion goes beyond the scope of the present paper.
Additional safety layer
In the case that the market goes down and the collective account becomes empty an additional safety layer can be introduced in both the accumulation and the retirement phases, see Fig. 1. This layer should be financed by a third party, for instance the employer in the case of occupational pension insurance. The investment form should be secure like government bonds or bank account.
The financial support procedure from the third layer has to be stipulated by contract and will depend on the specific product design, negotiations and requirements of the regulating authorities. If the proposed product is used as an occupational pension scheme, the employer might overtake the role of the third party by paying a certain amount of money, say monthly, into the third layer. Once the third layer is empty, no additional help will be provided.
However, in the extreme case that the third party agrees to overtake any unexpected losses, the product indeed will involve guarantees.
A particular risk accompanies the first years after the introduction of a new product. In case the market goes down, the additional safety layer will not contain a huge amount of money and might not be able to buffer the losses of the collective fund. If the additional layer becomes empty, a possible solution might be to distribute the available money from the collective account between the individual accounts according to a redistribution index specified contractually.
The retirement phase
In the retirement phase, we have a pure collective model (Collective account 2) and possibly an additional safety layer, as shown in Fig. 1. During the transition to the retirement phase the amount of the first pension has to be calculated due to indicators depending on the saved amount (individual account and part of the Collective account 1 according to the redistribution index) and some characteristics of the collective account in the retirement phase, for instance the degree of capital cover.
The target is to ensure the highest possible amount of initial pension and with low changes in the revaluation of pension payments. We follow a similar procedure like in the accumulation phase. However, the reference value is not the value of the collective account, but the degree of capital cover (DCC)—the ratio of the value of the collective fund and the present value of future pension payments for all current retirees.
The collective fund but also the value of the future pensions will develop over time, implying the development of the degree of capital cover. The first pensions of the new retirees should be calculated in such a way that the DCC does not change due to the new pensions to be paid and new capital transferred to the collective account in the retirement phase. The so-called “Betriebsrentenstärkungsgesetz” in Germany (the law came into force January 1st, 2018) requires the DCC to be inside the interval \([100\%,125\%]\). Thus, here a smoothing corridor is naturally defined. If the DCC drops below \(100\%\) the safety layer buffers the losses, as far as it is enough money, in such a way that the new DCC again amounts, for instance, to \(110\%\). If the additional safety layer is empty, the pensions should be cut to the level yielding the DCC of at least \(100\%\). Taking for instance \(110\%\) will make sure that DCC will not drop under \(100\%\) immediately after the adjustment, i.e. it acts as an additional buffer.
If the DCC exceeds \(125\%\), the pensions should be increased in such a way that the new DCC is not lower than \(110\%\). However, the insurance company has the freedom to choose the percentage of increase. Acting to the benefit of the insured, the insurance company can maximise the expected future pensions over all possible DCC values (from the interval \([110\%,125\%)\) determining the pension amount after the upward adjustment. The dilemma here is to decide whether it is better to increase the pensions as much as possible (set DCC to \(110\%\)) or to create an even bigger buffer (set the DCC to \(U\%\in (110\%,125\%)\)) preventing from possible future pension reductions due to a suboptimal market development.
Table 1 Comparison of the most common products