Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The Role of Financial Spinning, Learning, and Predation in Market Failure

  • Published:
Journal of the Knowledge Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines the possibility that market failures may be explained by predatory information flows between sellers and buyers when they act in dysfunctional relationships characterized by predator–prey dynamics and a behavioral pattern we define as “financial spinning.” The Global Financial Crisis serves as an example, among many others. It involved predatory mortgages and heavy securitization, and illustrates the fact that some sellers of toxic products (individuals and corporations) may have strong incentives to get buyers-prey to become disconnected from their financial needs, goals, and preferences, while accumulating debt. This may happen even in the context of a knowledge economy, and may lead the market towards failure. Computer-driven trajectory exploration based on learning-factored Lotka-Volterra equations shows that the predatory, noxious information is beneficial to sellers-predators but only up to a point. Consumers, for their part, are not always willing or able to receive sufficient information, which would otherwise allow them to protect themselves. Our approach may also guide corporations’ efforts towards improving their customer relationships, social image, and community participation. We contribute to the use of Lotka-Volterra equations and trajectory exploration in the context of predatory asymmetry of information at the interpersonal, sellers-buyers level, of spinning and of market failure.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1 
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Appendix 1 provides the main economic models attempting to explain/understand market failure by various scholars with their shortfalls.

  2. Indeed, the expression “burden” is mostly used in a legal context, such as “burden of proof,” or in an accounting framework. We use the term burden to assign the weight of responsibility that some consumers bear when acting as consumers. This is exemplified, for example, in the context of bio-responsible purchasing or when dealing with the burden of taxes (Cunningham, 2002).

  3. CAPM: Capital Asset Pricing Model, used extensively to approximate the expected rate of return of an asset (Levy, 2010).

  4. The absence of substitutes and of geographical expansion renders the debt trap consumers-prey fall in that much more lethal.

  5. This applies to all predators (active and inactive) and all prey (real and potential).

References

  • Abreu, D., & Brunnermeier, M. K. (2003). Bubbles and crashes. Econometrica, 71(1), 173–204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aguilera, R. V., & Vadera, A. K. (2008). The dark side of authority: Antecedents, mechanisms, and outcomes of organizational corruption. Journal of Business Ethics, 77(4), 431–449.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof, G. A., & Shiller, R. J. (2009). Animal spirits: How human psychology drives the economy, and why it matters for global capitalism. Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof, G., & Shiller, R. (2016). Manipulation and deception as part of a phishing equilibrium. Business Economics, 51(4), 207–221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alba, J. W., & Hutchinson, J. W. (1987). Dimensions of consumer expertise. Journal of Consumer Research, 13(4), 411–454.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allen, F., & Gale, D. (1999). Bubbles, crises, and policy. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 15(3), 9–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Almenberg, J., & Karapetyan, A. (2014). Hidden costs of hidden debt. Review of Finance, 18, 2247–2281.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Angie, A. D., Connelly, S., Waples, E. P., & Kligyte, V. (2011). The influence of discrete emotions on judgement and decision-making: A meta-analytic review. Cognition and Emotion, 25(8), 1393–1422.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1976). The economic approach to human behavior. University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ben-David, I. (2011). Financial constraints and inflated home prices during the real estate boom. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 55–87.

  • Bernanke, B. (2013). The Federal Reserve and the financial crisis. Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bettman, J. R., Luce, M. F., & Payne, J. W. (1998). Constructive consumer choice processes. Journal of Consumer Research, 25(3), 187–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bianco, K. (2008). The subprime lending crisis: Causes and effects of the mortgage meltdown. Wolters Kluwer Law & Business.

    Google Scholar 

  • Biggart, N. W., & Delbridge, R. (2004). Systems of exchange. Academy of Management Review, 29(1), 28–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blackwell, R. D., Engel, J. F., & Miniard, P. W. (2006). Consumer behavior (10th ed.). South Wester.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brunnermeier, M. K., & Oehmke, M. (2012). Bubbles, financial crises, and systemic risk. NBER Working Papers 1–90.

  • Brunnermeier, M. K., & Pedersen, L. H. (2009). Market liquidity and funding liquidity. Review of Financial Studies, 22(6), 2201–2238.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brunnermeier, M. K., & Sannikov, Y. (2014). A macroeconomic model with a financial sector. American Economic Review, 104(2), 379–421.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bucher-Koenen, T., & Ziegelmeyer, M. (2014). Once burned, twice shy? Financial Literacy and Wealth Losses during the Financial Crisis. Review of Finance, 18, 2215–2246.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Butcher, J. C. (2008). Numerical methods for ordinary differential equations. John Wiley & Sons.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C., Isacharoff, S., Loewenstein, G., O’Donoghue, T., & Rabin, M. (2003). Regulation for conservatives: Behavioral economics and the case for asymmetric paternalism. University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 151, 1211–1254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chaiken, S. (1980). Heuristic versus systematic information processing and the use of source versus message cues in persuasion. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 39(5), 752–766.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chakravarti, A. (2017). Imperfect information and opportunism. Journal of Economic Issues L, I(4), 1114–1136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cleeren, K., van Heerde, H. J., & Dekimpe, M. G. (2013). Rising from the ashes: How brands and categories can overcome product-harm crises. Journal of Marketing, 77(2), 58–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (CFPB). (2015). Financial well-being: The goal of financial education. http://www.consumerfinance.gov/reports/financial-well-being

  • Corneil, B. L., & McNamara, S. (2010). Lessons and consequences of the evolving 2007-? Credit Crunch. Aestimatio – The IEB International Journal of Finance 1, 164–181.

  • Crookes, D. J., & Blignaut, J. N. (2016) Predator–prey analysis using system dynamics: An application to the steel industry. SAJEMS Asset Research NS 19(5), 733–746 733.

  • Cunningham, L. A. (2002). Behavioral finance and investor governance. Washington and Lee Law Review, 59(3), 767–837.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dallery, T., & van Treeck, T. (2011). Conflicting claims and equilibrium adjustment processes in a stock-flow consistent macroeconomic model. Review of Political Economy, 23(2), 189–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dana, J., Weber, R. A., & Kuang, J. X. (2007). Exploiting moral wiggle room: Experiments demonstrating an illusory preference for fairness. Economic Theory, 33, 67–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dejuán, Ó., & Dejuán-Bitriá, D. (2016). A predator-prey model to explain cycles in financial-led economies. Accepted for publication.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deliema, M., Shadel, D., & Pak, K. (2019). Profiling victims of investment fraud: Mindsets and risky behaviors. Journal of Consumer Research, 46, 904–914.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delong, J. B., Schleifer, A., Summers, L. H., & Waldmann, R. J. (1990). Positive feedback investment strategies and destabilizing rational speculation. Journal of Finance, 45, 379–395.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dew, R., Ansari, A., & Li, Y. (2020). Modeling dynamic heterogeneity using Gaussian processes. Journal of Marketing Research, 57(1), 55–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ditzen, J. (2018). Cross-country convergence in a general Lotka-Volterra model. Spatial Economic Analysis, 13(2), 191–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dubina, I., Carayannis, E., & Campbell, D. (2012). Creativity economy and a crisis of the economy? Coevolution of knowledge, innovation, and creativity, and of the knowledge economy and knowledge society. Journal of the Knowledge Economy, 3(1), 1–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duflo, E., & Saez, E. (2003). The role of information and social interactions in retirement plan decisions: Evidence from a randomized experiment. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118, 815–842.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engle, R., & Ruan, T. (2019). Measuring the probability of a financial crisis. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 116(37), 18341–18346.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ericson, R. V., & Doyle, A. (2003). The moral risks of private justice: The case of insurance fraud. Risk and morality. University of Toronto Press Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. (1970). Efficient capital markets: A review of theory and empirical work. The Journal of Finance, 25(2), 383–417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernandes, D., Lynch, J. G., & Netemeyer, R. G. (2014). Financial literacy, financial education, and downstream financial behaviors. Management Science, 60(8), 1861–1883.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fishbein, M. A., & Ajzen, I. (1975). Belief, attitude, intention, and behavior: An introduction to theory and research. Reading, MA, Addison Wesley.

  • Fisher, K. L., & Statman, M. (2000). Investor sentiment and stock returns. Financial Analysts Journal, 56(2), 16–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fligstein, N., & Roehrkasse, A. F. (2016). The causes of fraud in the financial crisis of 2007 to 2009: Evidence from the mortgage-backed securities industry. American Sociological Review, 81(4), 617–643.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaganis, C., Galariotis, E., Pasiouras, F., & Staikouras, C. (2020). Bank profit efficiency and financial consumer protection policies. Journal of Business Research, 118, 98–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gheorghiu, G. (2013). Information asymmetries as the main source of market failure affecting the consumer. Ovidius University Annals, Series Economic Sciences, 13(1), 494–499.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser, E. L., Gyourko, J., & Saiz, A. (2008). Housing supply and housing bubbles. Journal of Urban Economics, 64, 198–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goodwin, R. M. (1967). A growth cycle. In Feinstein, C. H. (Ed.). Socialism, capitalism and economic growth. Cambridge University Press.

  • Gotelli, N. (1995). A primer of ecology. Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Graafland, J. J., & van de Ven, B. W. (2011). The credit crisis and the moral responsibility of professionals in finance. Journal of Business Ethics, 103, 605–619.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guiso, L., & Viviano, E. (2015). How much can financial literacy help? Review of Finance, 19, 1347–1382.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gurdgiev, C., & O’Loughlin, D. (2020). Herding and anchoring in cryptocurrency markets: Investor reaction to fear and uncertainty. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Finance, 25, 100271. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbef.2020.100271

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Habib, M. M., & Venditti, F. (2019). The global capital flows cycle: structural drivers and transmission channels. European Central Bank working paper 2280. https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/research/working-papers/html/index.en.html

  • Hadar, L., Sood, S., & Fox, C. R. (2013). Subjective knowledge in consumer financial decisions. Journal of Marketing Research L, 303–316.

  • Haggerty, N. (2021). Will banks be pulled into GameStop uproar? American Banker, 186(25), 6–7.

    Google Scholar 

  • Helweg-Larsen, M., & Shepperd, J. A. (2001). Do moderators of the optimistic bias affect personal or target risk estimates? A review of the literature. Personality and Social Psychology Review, 5(1), 74–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henry, J. F. (2012). The Veblenian predator and financial crises: Money, fraud, and a world of illusion. Journal of Economic Issues XLV, I(4), 989–1006.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hetzel, R. (2012). The Great Recession: Market failure or policy failure? (Studies in Macroeconomic History). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511997563

  • Hill, R. P., & Kozup, J. C. (2007). Consumer experiences with predatory practices. The Journal of Consumer Affairs, 41(1), 29–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoechle, D., Ruenzi, S., Schaub, N., & Schmid, M. (2017). The impact of financial advice on trade performance and behavioral biases. Review of Finance, 871–910.

  • Hoffmann, M., Krause, M. U., & Laubach, T. (2012). Trend growth expectations and US house prices before and after the crisis. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 83(3), 394–409.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holtfreter, K., Reisig, M. D., & Pratt, T. C. (2008). Low self-control, routine activities, and fraud victimization. Criminology, 46(1), 189–220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Howard, J. A., & Sheth, J. N. (1969). The theory of buyer behavior. John Wiley & Sons Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huang, J.-Z., Huang, W., & Ni, J. (2019). Predicting bitcoin returns using high-dimensional technical indicators. The Journal of Finance and Data Science, 5(3), 140–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huck, N., Mavoori, H., & Mesly, O. (2019). The rationality of irrationality in times of financial crises. Economic Modelling. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2019.10.033

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iacoviello, M. (2008). Household debt and income inequality, 1963–2003. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 40(5), 929–965.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D. (2011). Thinking, fast and slow. Penguin Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karlsson, N., Loewenstein, G., & Seppi, D. (2009). The ostrich effect: Selective attention to information. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 38(2), 95–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J. M. (2006). The general theory of employment, interest and money. Atlantic Publishers and Distributors (P) Limited.

  • Kim, H. (2013). Situational materialism: How entering lotteries may undermine self-control. Journal of Consumer Research, 40(4), 759–772.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kiyotaki, N., & Moore, J. (1997). Credit cycles. Journal of Political Economy, 105(2), 211–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. (2009). Reagan did it. International Herald Tribune (June 2).

  • Lee, C. J., & Andrade, E. B. (2011). Fear, social projection, and financial decision making, Journal of Marketing Research XLVIII, S121–S129.

  • Lee, J. J. (2016). Ambiguity aversion: Theoretical advances and practical implications. Journal of Marketing, 3(3), 111–172.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levy, H. (2010). The CAPM is alive and well: A review and synthesis. European Financial Management 16(1), 2010, 43–71.

  • Lucas, R. E., Jr. (1981). Studies in business-cycle theory. MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lunn, P. (2015). Are consumer decision-making phenomena a fourth market failure? Journal of Consumer Policy, 38(3), 315–330.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lusardi, A., & Mitchell, O. (2014). The economic importance of financial literacy: Theory and organization. Journal of Economic Literature, 52(1), 5–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manconi, A., Massa, M., & Yasuda, A. (2010). The behavior of intoxicated investors: The role of institutional investors in propagating the crisis of 2007–2008. NBER Working Paper Series Paper 16191. https://www.nber.org/papers/w16191.pdf

  • Martin, N., & Morich, K. (2011). Unconscious mental processes in consumer choice: Toward a new model of consumer behavior. Journal of Brand Management, 18(7), 483–505.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mehta, N., Rajiv, S., & Srinivasan, K. (2004). Role of forgetting in memory-based choice decisions: A structural model. Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 2(2), 107–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mesly, O. (2020). Consumer spinning: Zooming in zooming in an atypical consumer behavior. Journal of Macromarketing, 25–31.

  • Mesly, O., Chkir, I., & Racicot, F.-E. (2018). Predatory cells and puzzling financial crises: Are toxic products good for the financial markets? Economic Modelling, 78, 11–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mesly, O., Nicolas Huck, H., Shanafelt, D. W., & Racicot, F. É. (2020). From wheel of fortune to wheel of misfortune: Financial crises, cycles, and consumer predation. Journal of Consumer Affairs (in print).

  • Miles, D. (2015). Housing, leverage, and stability in the wider economy. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 47(S1), 19–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moore, J. F. (1993). Predators and prey: A new ecology of competition. Harvard Business Review May-June, 75–86.

  • Nasritdinov, G., & Dalimov, R. (2010). Limit cycle, trophic function and the dynamics of intersectoral interaction. Current Research Journal of Economic Theory, 2(2), 32–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rajan, R. (2010). Fault Lines. Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reckwitz, A. (2002). The status of the “material” in theories of culture: From “social structure” to “artefacts.” Journal for the Theory of Social Behaviour, 32(2), 195–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roy, S., & Kemme, D. M. (2012). Causes of banking crises: Deregulation, credit booms and asset bubbles, then and now. International Review of Economics and Finance, 24, 270–294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sama, L. M., & Shoaf, V. (2005). Reconciling rules and principles: An ethics-based approach to corporate governance. Journal of Business Ethics, 58, 177–185.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, L. (2016). Game theory in economics and beyond. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 30(4), 107–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1971). Generalized predator-prey oscillations in ecological and economic equilibrium. Proc. Nat. Acad. Sci. U. S. a., 68, 980–983.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scherbina, A. (2013). Asset price bubbles: A selective survey. International Monetary Fund (IMF) working paper WP13/45, Institute for Capacity Development, 1–40.

  • Sévi, B., & Yafil, F. (2005). A special case of self-protection: The choice of a lawyer. Economic Bulletin, 4, 1–8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shiller, R. J. (2005). Irrational exuberance. Crown Publishing Group, a division of Random House Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skott, P., & Ryoo, S. (2008). Macroeconomic implications of financialization. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 32(6), 827–862.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. L. (2003). Constructivist and ecological rationality in economics. The American Economic Review, 93(3), 465–508.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R. M., Lo, A. W., & Blinder, A. S. (2012). Rethinking the financial crisis. Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Song, F., & Thakor, A. V. (2010). Financial system architecture and the co-evolution of banks and capital markets. The Economic Journal, 120, 1021–1055.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sornette, D. (2017). Stock markets crash: Critical events in complex financial systems. Series: Princeton Science Library. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

  • Starcke, K., & Brand, M. (2012). Decision making under stress: A selective review. Neuroscience and Biobehavioral Reviews, 36, 1228–1248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. E. (2003). Government failure vs. market failure: Principles of regulation. JES.Govt.Failure.Mkt.Failure%20(1).pdf.

  • Trimbath, S. (2015). Ten steps to stable financial markets. Spiramus Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • van Rooij, M., Lusardi, A., & Alessie, R. (2011). Financial literacy and stock market participation. Journal of Financial Economics, 101, 449–472.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Treeck, T. (2014). Did inequality cause the U.S. financial crisis? Journal of Economic Surveys, 28(3), 421–448

  • Williamson, O. E. (1981). The economics of organization: The transaction cost approach. American Journal of Sociology, 87(3), 548–577.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yoon, C., Laurent, G., Fung, H., Gonzalez, R., Gutchess, A., Hedden, T., & Skurnik, I. (2005). Cognition, persuasion and decision making in older consumers. Marketing Letters, 16(3), 429–441.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zerbe, R. O., Jr., & McCurdy, H. E. (1999). The failure of market failure. Journal of Policy Analysis & Management, 18(4), 558–578.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, Y. (2012). A Lotka-Volterra evolutionary model of China’s incremental institutional Reform. Applied Economics Letters, 19, 367–371.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Olivier Mesly.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of Interest

The authors declare no competing interests.

Disclaimer

All authors certify that they have no affiliations with or involvement in any organization or entity with any financial interest or non-financial interest in the subject matter or materials discussed in this manuscript.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1. Main economic models attempting to explain/understand market failures

Model

Scholarly authors

Year

Shortfall

SRISK

Engle & Ruan

2019

The behavioral aspects of market agents largely ignored

Global financial cycle

Habib & Venditti, European Central Bank

2019

Discuss risk aversion, but not speculation

Predatory dynamics

Huck et al

2019

No discussion on spinning

Animal Spirits

Akerlof & Shiller

2016

Do not anchor opportunistic behaviors in a larger frame that includes business cycles

Macroeconomic model

Brunnermeier & Sannikov

2014

Discuss volatility, but not moral hazards generated by market agents

Financial accelerator and the role of the Federal Reserve

Bernanke

2013

Does not explain the mathematical link between consumers and suppliers’ behaviors

Liquidity spiral

Brunnermeier & Oehmke

2012

Do not address in-depth how toxic products infect markets

Bubbles and crashes

Abreu & Brunnermeier

2003

Address rationality but not moral hazard

Opportunism and contract theory

Williamson

1981

Opposes trust to opportunistic behaviors in contractual agreements without reference to business cycles

Credit cycles

Kiyotaki & Moore

1997

Do not link impatience to speculation

Appendix 2. List of parameters used in the spinning model

Trajectory

1

2

3

4

5

 

Stable oscillations

Spiral/Convergence

Learning, Prey + , oscillations

Learning, Pred + , oscillations

Spiral + Predator learning

Learning

No

No

Yes

Yes

Yes

S

0

0

-1

1

1

Α

0.02

0.20

0.02

0.03

0.50

Β

0.003

0.010

0.003

0.003

0.020

ϒ

0.03

0.08

0.05

0.05

0.20

δ (or δ0 if learning)

0.0010

0.0010

0.0015

0.0015

0.0010

L

0.000000

0.000000

0.000001

0.000400

0.005000

Nb Prey (initial)

50

100

19

50

100

Nb Pred (initial)

10

10

5

10

10

Nb periods

1000

1000

950

810

1000

Time step

0.100

2.000

0.001

0.010

1.000

Number of points

10000

500

950000

81000

1000

  1. Nb number, pred predators

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Mesly, O., Mavoori, H. & Huck, N. The Role of Financial Spinning, Learning, and Predation in Market Failure. J Knowl Econ 14, 517–543 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s13132-021-00862-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s13132-021-00862-2

Keywords

Navigation