Skip to main content
Log in

Attributing Value to Patents and Trademarks in Complex Production Chains

  • Published:
Journal of the Knowledge Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This article analyzes the value of a product’s surplus attributable to intellectual property (IP, such as patents or trademarks) relative to the product’s overall value. In a complex production process, learning by doing allows a leading firm to gain some surplus without IP, and as the number of steps approaches infinity, the surplus attributable to IP approaches zero. The value of the same IP held for licensing purposes, rather than to protect a production monopoly, shows no such convergence to zero. The model is used to explain the empirically observed differences between the use patterns of IP in industries based on discrete products, where patents are typically used to maintain monopolies, versus industries based on complex products, where patents are primarily licensing tools. The result is also applied to the questions of evaluating arm’s length transfers, which are often used to move revenue to tax-discounted IP boxes, and for discussion of non-practicing entities.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Prospectus of RPX Corp, http://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/1509432/000119312511124791/d424b4.htm

  2. State aid decision for SA.46470 (2017/NN) — Netherlands, “Possible State aid in favour of Inter IKEA.” European Commission, Brussels, 18 December 2017, §165.

  3. As r rises, ert decreases for all values of t. As Ln rises, p(tLn, s) decreases, by the assumption that p is increasing in its first term, and the area over which the integral is computed shrinks, reaching zero when Ln = Lp.

  4. Proof that \(\partial ({\int \limits } p)/\partial s > 0\): uniform convergence allows us to write this derivative of an integral as the integral of a derivative:

    $$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \partial (\int p)/\partial s &=& {\int}_{L_{n}}^{L_{p}} \frac{\partial p}{\partial s}e^{-rt}dt\\ &=& {\int}_{L_{n}}^{L_{p}} \ln\left( \frac{t}{t+1}\right)\left( \frac{t}{t+1}\right)^{s} e^{-rt}dt \end{array} $$

    which is always negative for t,s > 0.

  5. This can be formalized: consider a firm that uses k patentable components, each of which has at least a strictly positive chance 𝜖 of being independently invented. Then the likelihood of some patent being independently invented is 1 − (1 − 𝜖)k, which approaches one as k rises.

  6. After a Supreme Court appeal [137 S. Ct. 429, 196 L. Ed. 2d 363 (2016)] and several retrials, the damages were reduced from the full product value of just over 1billionto539 million, including damages.

  7. http://www.ipaustralia.gov.au/get-the-right-ip/patents/types-of-patents/innovation-patent/

References

Download references

Acknowledgments

Thanks to John Asker, Jennifer 8. Lee, Bill Morgan, Mike McDonald, Ryan Nunn, and Neviana Petkova for the discussion and commentary.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ben Klemens.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Klemens, B. Attributing Value to Patents and Trademarks in Complex Production Chains. J Knowl Econ 12, 842–875 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s13132-020-00629-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s13132-020-00629-1

Keywords

Navigation