Advertisement

Journal of the Knowledge Economy

, Volume 9, Issue 1, pp 17–39 | Cite as

Expectation Formation in a New Keynesian Economy: Evidence from a Laboratory Experiment

  • Abhishek Das
  • Arpita Ghose
  • Gautam Gupta
Article
  • 115 Downloads

Abstract

This paper discusses an experimental study on the formation of expectation within a New Keynesian macroeconomic framework. The novelty of this paper (one of the earlier paper) is that each subject was asked to forecast both the inflation rate and output gap at the same time, which is an improvement over the existing literature. We find a lot of heterogeneity in expectation formation and also the model switching nature by the subjects.

Keywords

Experimental economics Inflation expectations Output gap expectation New Keynesian model Taylor rule 

JEL Classification

C91 C92 E37 E52 

Notes

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank Ajitava Raychaudhuri and Ambar Nath Ghosh for the helpful suggestions. Financial support from the Social Science and Cultural Resources program, UPE II, Jadavpur University, made the study possible for which we are grateful.

Compliance with Ethical Standards

Conflict of Interest

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.

References

  1. Adam, K. (2007). Experimental evidence on the persistence of output and inflation. Economic Journal, 117(520), 603–636.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Anufriev, M., & Hommes, C. (2008). Evolutionary selection of individual expectations and aggregate outcomes. Mimeo: University of Amsterdam.Google Scholar
  3. Arifovic, J., & Sargent T. J. (2003). Experiments with human subjects in a Kydland-Prescott Phillips curve economy. In: D., Altig, B. Smith, (Eds.), The origins and evolution of central banking: volume to inaugurate the institute on central banking of the federal reserve bank of Cleveland (pp. 23–56). Cambridge University Press,.Google Scholar
  4. Assenza, T. &Heemeijer, P. & Hommes, C.H. &Massaro, D. (2011): Individual expectations and aggregate macro behavior, CeNDEF Working Papers 11–01, Universiteit van Amsterdam, Center for Nonlinear Dynamics in Economics and FinanceGoogle Scholar
  5. Baak, S. J. (1999). Tests for bounded rationality with a linear dynamic model distorted by heterogeneous expectations. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 23(9–10), 1517.1543.Google Scholar
  6. Becker, O. (1967): Experimentelle Untersuchung der ErwartungsbildungfüreineZeitreihe, In: Sauermann, H. (Ed.), Beiträgezur Experimentellen Wirtschaftsforschung. Tübingen. 226–254.Google Scholar
  7. Becker, O., & Bolle. (1996). Expectation in economics: rational or not? Evidence from experiments. JahrbuchÖkonomie und Gesellschaft, 13, 88–99.Google Scholar
  8. Becker, O., & Leopold-Wildburger, U. (1996). The bounds and likelihood procedure: a simulation study concerning the efficiency of visual forecasting techniques. Central European Journal of Operations Research and Economics, 4, 223–229.Google Scholar
  9. Becker, O., & Leopold-Wildburger, U. (2000). Erwartungsbildung und Prognose Ergebnisseeiner experimentellen Studie. Austrian Journa of Statistics, 29, 7–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Bernasconi, M., & Kirchkamp, O. (2000). Why do monetary policies matter? An experimental study of saving and inflation in an overlapping generations model. Journal of Monetary Economics, 46(2), 315.343.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Branch, W. A. (2004). The theory of rationally heterogeneous expectation: evidence from survey data on inflation expectations. Economic Journal, 114(497), 592–621.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Branch, W. A. (2007). Sticky information and model uncertainty in survey data on inflation expectations. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 31(1), 245–276.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Clarida, R., Gali, J., & Gertler, M. (2000). Monetary policy rules and macroeconomic stability: evidence and some theory. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(1), 147–180.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Das, A. (2009). Heterogeneity in inflation expectation: an experimental economics approach, M.Phil Dissertation, Department of Economics, Jadavpur University, India.Google Scholar
  15. Das, A., Ghosh, A., & Gupta, G. (2012). Expectation Formation in a New Keynesian model: evidence from an experiment, working paper # 07–12. India: Department of Economics, Jadavpur University.Google Scholar
  16. Dwyer, G. P., Jr., Williams, A. W., Battalio, R. C., & Mason, T. I. (1993). Tests of rational expectations in a stark setting. Economic Journal, 103, 586–601.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Evans, G. W., and S., Honkapohja (2001). Learning and expectations in macroeconomics. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  18. Ezekiel, M. (1938). The cobweb theorem. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 52(2), 255–280.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Fehr, E., & Tyran, J.-R. (2008). Limited rationality and strategic interaction: the impact of the strategic environment on nominal inertia. Econometrica, Econometric Society, 76(2), 353–394.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Fisher, F.M. (1962): A priori information and time series analysis, AmsterdamGoogle Scholar
  21. Haruvy, E., Lahav, Y., & Noussair, C. N. (2007). Traders’ expectations in asset markets: experimental evidence. American Economic Review, 97, 1901–1920.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Hey, J. D. (1994). Expectations formation: rational or adaptive or …? Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 25, 329–344.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Hommes, C. (2011). The heterogeneous expectations hypothesis: some evidence from the lab. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Elsevier, 35(1), 1–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Hommes, C., Huang, H., & Wang, D. (2005a). A robust rational route to randomness in a simple asset pricing model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 29(6), 1043–1072.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Hommes, C., Sonnemans, J., Tuinstra, J., & van de Velden, H. (2005b). Coordination of expectations in asset pricing experiments. Review of Financial Studies, 18(3), 955–980.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Kelley, H., and D., Friedman (2008). Learning to forecast rationally, in handbook of experimental economics results, ed. by C. R. Plott, and V. L. Smith, vol. 1, chap. 35, pp. 303–310. Elsevier.Google Scholar
  27. Lucas, R. E. (1986). Adaptive behavior and economic theory. Journal of Business, 59(4), S401–S426.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Marimon, R., & Sunder, S. (1993). Indeterminacy of equilibria in a hyperinflationary world: experimental evidence. Econometrica, 61, 1073–1107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Marimon, R., & Sunder, S. (1994). Expectations and learning under alternative monetary regimes: an experimental approach. Economic Theory, 4, 131–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Marimon, R., & Sunder, S. (1995). Does a constant money growth rule help stabilize inflation? Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 43, 111–156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. McCallum, B. T., & Nelson, E. (2004). Timeless perspective vs. discretionary monetary policy in forward-looking models. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 86(2), 43–56.Google Scholar
  32. Pfajfar, D., and B., Žakelj (2011). Experimental evidence on inflation expectation formation. Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1332982;lastaccessed on 26th July 2011.
  33. Pfajfar, D., & Santoro, E. (2007). Heterogeneity and learning in inflation expectation formation: an empirical assessment. Mimeo: University of Cambridge.Google Scholar
  34. Schmalensee, R. (1976). An experimental study of expectation formation. Econometrica, 44(1), 17–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Williams, A. W. (1987). The formation of price forecasts in experimental markets. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 19(1), 1–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media New York 2015

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of EconomicsJadavpur UniversityKolkataIndia

Personalised recommendations