Abstract
Welfare state policies in the United States have expanded significantly, with some short-term fluctuations, since the 1940s. This paper examines the politics of ethnic heterogeneity in order to explain these welfare state changes. Results from various time-series regressions of public social transfer expenditures with or without health suggest welfare state-limiting roles of race and immigration, with the growing religious heterogeneity consistently helping to bolster welfare state policies. Albeit more nuanced than groundbreaking, findings help understand the nature of the American welfare state politics driven in part by the way ethnic heterogeneity shapes the evolving public opinion and policy preferences.
This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.




Notes
To cite an example, recent immigrants do not qualify for Food Stamps or TANF supports even when they are granted permission to live and work as permanent residents (Wagle, 2012).
Operationally, an alternative to using the relative size of ethno-racial and religious minorities would be to use “fractionalization measures” which include all possible ethnic groups in calculation (Alesina and La Ferrara 2005). While this approach is more widely used in the literature, the reason for not adopting it has to do with the requirement of detailed data on specific ethno-racial and religious groups. More important than this aggregation procedure, however, is the accuracy of data since there are many such groups on which historical data are unavailable.
An important indicator of this demand would be poverty for which consistent historical data are not unavailable. Also, descriptive statistics of the power resources and demographic and economic variables including GDP growth, unemployment, population 65 and over, population size, union density, and Democratic control of government are presented in Table 3. A note is also in order on the way the Democratic control of government is measured: by aggregating data on the Democratic control of presidency (1/2), Senate (1/4), and House (1/4) in any given year. While this measure fails to account for other nuances of party control, it provides a reasonable basis to incorporate partisan politics as relevant to policymaking in the United States.
While this adjustment could be made by focusing on all of the economically inactive population, such adjustment would not be useful. Despite qualification for some unemployment insurance and child tax credits, social transfer benefits available to children, the unemployed, and those out of the labor force do not compare well with those of the elderly who qualify for Social Security, Medicare, and a host of other programs.
This method is chosen for its ability to handle models with explanatory variables that are not strictly exogenous, making alternative methods such as Prais–Winston or Cochrane–Orcutt not fully consistent (Wooldridge 2009). But the procedure of lagging this way creates a two-way lag, in which the Newey–West lags apply to the already lagged dependent variables, something methodologically plausible for models with potential serial correlation. Although this goes further than typically required, the goal is to rule out any of such methodological concerns. Results also show that lagging is in fact beneficial empirically.
The archives of Social Security Bulletins serve as the unified source of data on public expenditures on welfare state transfers. Data on population including ethno-racial heterogeneity and foreign-born population are derived from the Census Bureau. Data on naturalized citizens are derived from the Department of Homeland Security and those on net migration are derived from the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. Because the Census Bureau lacks historical data on religious breakdowns, aggregate data from the Gallop Poll monthly random samples provide reasonable basis to incorporate trends on religious minorities over time.
This can give the impression of the presence of significant missing data which, as can be gleaned from Table 1, is limited to religious and immigration variables especially at the beginning of the time series.
This aggregation involves taking simple average of “pre-transformed” scales of the three immigration variables. This pre-transformation follows the equation, \(X_{\text{Index}} = \frac{{X_{i} - X_{\text{Min}} }}{{X_{\text{Max}} - X_{\text{Min}} }}\), where Xi is the given value for a specific year, and XMin and XMax are the minimum and maximum values, respectively. The resulting aggregate immigration index can range between zero (none) and 100 (the highest possible).
While the dependent variable, welfare state expenditures relative to GDP (with and without health), remains unchanged, models are estimated with alternative specifications allowing sensitivity analysis. To avoid potential multicollinearity, specifications vary by introducing one ethnic heterogeneity variable at a time, except for a model variation in which all three measures of immigration are used simultaneously given their unitary focus. A model variation incorporating a unified immigration index also helps examine further sensitivity due to potential multicollinearity of the three immigration measures. Model estimates are mostly consistent across the different specifications, indicating that the observed results do not emanate from random chance alone. Some of the differences in results emanate from sample sizes varying across specifications.
While this could be carried out for the adjusted measures as well, results would not be significantly different.
This exercise can also be extended to expenditures excluding health and/or unadjusted expenditures.
References
Adloff, F. (2006). Religion and social-political action: The Catholic church, Catholic charities, and the American welfare state. International Review of Sociology, 16(1), 1–30.
Alesina, A., Baqir, R., & Easterly, W. (1999). Public goods and ethnic divisions. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(4), 1243–1284.
Alesina, A., & Glaeser, E. (2004). Fighting poverty in the US and Europe: a world of difference. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Alesina, A., Glaeser, E., & Sacerdote, B. (2001). Why doesn’t the United States have a European-style welfare state? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2, 187–277.
Alesina, A., & La Ferrara, E. (2005). Ethnic diversity and economic performance. Journal of Economic Literature, 43, 762–800.
Allport, G. (1958). The nature of prejudice. Garden City: Doubleday.
Banting, K. (2010). Is there a progressive dilemma in Canada? immigration, multiculturalism, and the welfare state. Canadian Journal of Political Science, 43(4), 797–820.
Belcher, J., Fandetti, D., & Cole, D. (2004). Is Christian religious conservatism compatible with the liberal social welfare state? Social Work, 49(2), 269–276.
Benabou, R., & Tirole, J. (2006). Belief and just world and redistributive politics. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(2), 699–746.
Bitler, M., & Hoynes, H. (2013). Immigrants, welfare reform, and the U.S. safety net. In D. Card & S. Raphael (Eds.), Immigration, poverty, and socioeconomic inequality (pp. 315–380). New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Borjas, G., & Hilton, L. (1996). Immigration and the welfare state: immigrant participation in means-tested entitlement programs. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111(2), 575–604.
Brady, D. (2009). Rich democracies, poor people: How politics explain poverty. New York: Oxford University Press.
Brady, D., & Finnigan, R. (2014). Does immigration undermine public support for social policy? American Sociological Review, 79(1), 17–42.
Brown, H. (2013). Racialized conflicts and policy spillover effects: the role of race in the contemporary U.S. welfare state. American Journal of Sociology, 119(2), 394–443.
Crepaz, M. (2008). Trust beyond borders: Immigration, the welfare state, and identity in modern societies. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.
Esping-Andersen, G. (1990). The three worlds of welfare capitalism. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Esping-Andersen, G. (1999). Social foundations of postindustrial economies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Fording, R. (2003). “Laboratories of democracy” or symbolic politics? In S. Schram, J. Soss, & R. Fording (Eds.), Race and the politics of welfare reform (pp. 72–97). Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.
Fox, C. (2012). Three worlds of relief: race, immigration, and the American welfare state from the Progressive Era to the New Deal. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Fox, C., Bloemraad, I., & Kesler, C. (2013). Immigration and redistributive social policy. In D. Card & S. Raphael (Eds.), Immigration, poverty, and socioeconomic inequality (pp. 381–420). New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Gaertner, S. L., & Dovidio, J. (2000). Reducing intergroup bias: The common group identity model. Philadelphia: Psychology Press.
Gibson, J. L. (2010). The political consequences of religiosity: does religion always cause political intolerance? In A. Wolf & I. Katsnelson (Eds.), Religion and democracy in the United States: Danger or opportunity? (pp. 147–175). Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Gilens, M. (1999). Why Americans hate welfare, race, media, and the politics of antipoverty policy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Gilens, M. (2003). How the poor became black: The racialization of American poverty in the mass-media. In S. Schran, J. Soss, & R. Fording (Eds.), Race and the politics of welfare reform (pp. 101–130). Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Gill, A., & Lundsgaarde, E. (2004). welfare state spending and religiosity: A cross-national analysis. Rationality and Society, 16(4), 399–436.
Glazer, N., & Moynihan, D. P. (1970). Beyond the melting pot: The negroes, Puerto Ricans, Jews, Italians, and Irish of New York City. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Graham, C., & Crown, S. (2014). Religion and wellbeing around the world: Social time, social purpose, or social insurance? International Journal of Wellbeing, 4(1), 1–27.
Hacker, J. (2002). The Divided welfare state: The battle over public and private social benefits in the United States. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Hacker, J., & Pierson, P. (2002). Business power and social policy: Employers and the formation of an American welfare state. Politics and Society, 30(2), 277–325.
Hero, R., & Preuhs, R. (2007). Immigration and the evolving American welfare state: Examining policies in the U.S. States. American Journal of Political Science, 51(3), 498–517.
Hicks, A. (1999). Social democracy and welfare capitalism: A century of income security politics. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Huber, E., & Stephens, J. (2001). Development and crisis of the welfare state. Chicago: Chicago University Press.
Isaacs, H. (1975). Idols of the tribe: Group identity and political change. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Iversen, T., & Cusack, T. R. (2000). Causes of welfare state expansion: Deindustrialization or globalization? World Politics, 52, 313–349.
Jordan, J. (2014). Religion and inequality: The lasting impact of religious traditions and institutions on welfare state development. European Political Science Review. https://doi.org/10.1017/s1755773914000381.
Korpi, W. (1983). The democratic class struggle. London: Routledge.
Korpi, W. (1989). Power politics and state autonomy in the development of social citizenship: Social rights during sickness in 18 OECD countries since 1930. American Sociological Review, 54(3), 309–328.
Korpi, W., & Palme, J. (2003). New politics and class politics in the context of austerity and globalization: welfare state regress in eighteen countries, 1975–1995. American Political Science Review, 97(3), 425–446.
Larsen, C. (2011). Ethnic heterogeneity and public support for welfare: is the American experience replicated in Britain, Sweden, and Denmark? Scandinavian Political Studies, 34(4), 332–353.
Lee, W., Roemer, J., & Straeten, K. (2006). Racism, xenophobia, and redistribution. Journal of European Economic Association, 4(2–3), 446–454.
Liberman, R. (1998). Shifting the color line: Race and the American welfare state. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Macey, M., & Carling, A. (2011). Ethnic, racial, and religious inequalities: The perils of subjectivity. Hampshire: Palgrave Macmillan.
Malesevic, S. (2004). The sociology of ethnicity. London: Sage Publications.
Neustadt, I. (2011). Do religious beliefs explain preferences for income redistribution? Experimental evidence. CESifo Economic Studies, 57(4), 623–652.
Opielka, M. (2008). Christian foundations of the welfare state: Strong cultural values in comparative perspective. In W. van Oorschoot, M. Opielka, & B. Pfau-Effinger (Eds.), Culture and welfare state: Values and social policy in comparative perspective (pp. 89–114). Northampton: Edward Elgar.
Pierson, P. (1996). The New politics of welfare state. World Politics, 48(2), 143–179.
Pierson, P. (Ed.). (2001). The new politics of welfare state. New York: Oxford University Press.
Quadagno, J. (1994). The color of welfare: How racism undermined the war on poverty. New York: Oxford University Press.
Quadagno, J. (1998). Race, class, and gender in the US welfare state: Nixon’s failed family assistance plan. In J. S. O’Connor & G. M. Olson (Eds.), Power resources theory and the welfare state: A critical approach (pp. 250–283). Toronto: University of Toronto Press.
Scruggs, L., & Allan, J. (2006). Welfare state decommodification in 18 OECD countries: A replication and revision. Journal of European Social Policy, 16(1), 55–72.
Soroka, S., Banting, K., & Johnston, R. (2006). Immigration and redistribution in a global era. In S. Bowles, P. Bardhan, & M. Wallerstein (Eds.), Globalization and egalitarian redistribution (pp. 261–288). Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Soss, J., Fording, R., & Schram, S. (2008). The color of devolution: race, federalism, and the politics of social control. American Journal of Political Science, 52(3), 536–553.
Soss, J., Fording, R., & Schram, S. (2011). Disciplining the poor: Neoliberal paternalism and the persistent power of race. Chicago: Chicago University Press.
Soss, J., Schram, S., Vertanian, T., & O’Brian, E. (2001). Setting the terms of relief: Setting the state policy choices in the devolution revolution. American Journal of Political Science, 45(2), 378–395.
Stephens, J. D. (1979). The transition from capitalism to socialism. London: Macmillan.
Taylor, C. (1992). In A. Gutmann (Ed.), Multiculturalism and the politics of recognition. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Taylor-Gooby, P. (2005). Is the future American? Or, can left politics preserve European welfare states from erosion through growing ‘racial’ diversity? Journal of Social Policy, 34(4), 661–672.
Tocqueville, A. (1835). Democracy in America. The Project Gutenberg EBook series# 816 (H. Reeve, Trans., January 21, 2006); http://www.gutenberg.org.
Van Kersbergen, K. (2009). Religion and the welfare state in the Netherlands. In K. Van Kersbergen & P. Manow (Eds.), Religion, class coalitions, and welfare states (pp. 119–145). New York: Cambridge University Press.
Van Kersbergen, K., & Manow, P. (Eds.). (2009). Religion, class coalitions, and welfare states. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Van Oorschot, W. (2007). Solidarity towards immigrants in European welfare states. International Journal of Social Welfare, 17(1), 3–14.
Wagle, U. (2012). The Food Stamps program and economic security among low income families, part I. Poverty & Public Policy, 4(4), 223–238.
Wagle, U. (2013a). The heterogeneity link of the welfare state and redistribution. New York: Springer.
Wagle, U. (2013b). The heterogeneity politics of welfare state: changing population heterogeneity and welfare state policies in high-income OECD countries, 1980–2005. Politics & Policy, 41(6), 947–984.
Wilensky, H. (1975). The welfare state and state equality: Structural and ideological roots of public expenditures. Berkley: University of California Press.
Wilensky, H. (2002). Rich democracies: Political economy, public policy, and performance. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Williams, B. F. (1989). Anthropology and the race to nation across ethnic terrain. Annual Review of Anthropology, 18, 401–444.
Wooldridge, J. (2009). Introductory econometrics: A modern approach. Mason: Thompson South-Western.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Additional information
Publisher's Note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Wagle, U.R. Ethnic Heterogeneity Politics of Welfare State in the United States: A Time Series Analysis, 1940–2016. Race Soc Probl 11, 185–204 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12552-019-09261-4
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12552-019-09261-4