Skip to main content
Log in

Electrification, the Smoot-Hawley tariff bill and the stock market boom and crash of 1929: evidence from longitudinal data

  • Published:
Journal of Economics and Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Electrification and the introduction of high-throughput, continuous-flow production tech- niques in the 1920s vastly increased America’s capacity to produce wealth. Getting in the way, according to many, were weak product markets, prompting ranking Republicans Reed Smoot and Ellis Hawley, in the Party’s 1928 presidential platform, to advocate yet another generalized upward tariff revision—the Smoot-Hawley Tariff Bill (SHTB). The stock market responded favorably, as prices increased throughout 1928 and most of 1929. They crashed, however, in October 1929 when it became evident that the proposed Smoot-Hawley Tariff Bill which called for across-the-board tariff would be defeated by an Insurgent-Republican Democrat coalition and replaced with substantially lower tariffs on manufactures. Using longitudinal analysis, this paper shows how stock prices of firms in industries most affected by electrification tracked these developments, rising in response to good tariff news, and falling in response to bad tariff news. Operationally, a tariff news proxy variable is developed and included in the three-factor Fama-French model of stock prices. Our hypothesis is then tested using daily stock returns for a subsample of nineteen DJIA firms. The results show a positive and significant effect of tariff news on all nineteen stock prices. Lastly, we show that good tariff news explains up to 76% of stock price appreciation in the 1928–1929 period of firms in industries most affected by electrification. These results suggest that the stock market boom and crash of 1929 can be understood in terms of political developments set against a background of improved fundamentals.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Longitudinal event studies are mostly used in epidemiology and psychology to track subjects over time, identifying various causal events.

  2. Our analysis extends Fisher’s original argument and McGrattan and Prescott’s 2004 results by (i) providing a testable theory of the technology shock that prompted the stock market boom and (ii) a theory of stock-price appreciation and depreciation. McGrattan and Prescott were unable to address the question of why the market crashed.

  3. McGrattan and Prescott (2004) rhetorically asked: “If stock prices were not inflated beyond their fundamental values in October 1929, why did the market crash?” They then pointed out that: “Answering that question is not addressed here.” (McGrattan and Prescott 2004, 992).

  4. Of the twelve Insurgent Republicans that had voted in favor of the McMaster Resolution on January 15, 1928 (Senators Blain, Borah, Broookhart, Capper, Frazier, Howell, La Pollette, McMaster, Norbeck, Norris, Nye and Pine), six voted against the Thomas Recommital Plan (Borah, Brookhart, Capper, La Follette, Norbeck and Norris), while five voted in favor (Frazier, Howell, McMaster, Nye, and Pine).

  5. The choice of DJIA firms was based on Rappoport and White (1994). Retailing firms, Sears and Woolworths, as well as Paramount and Wright Aeronautical were excluded for lack of data on industry electrification.

  6. The New York Times and the Wall Street Journal are two of the most-used information sources in event studies, be they economic, financial, environmental, etc. See for example, Binder (1985). The choice of the New York Times was based on its representativeness, and its status as the premier source of information in the North-East—and New York City. It bears noting that none of the new events involved either newspaper or

    contributor editorials.

  7. The data as well as the coded news events are available from the author.

  8. The DJIA rebounded on October 31, only to return to the 230 point level three days later, where it stood for a few days before hitting its all-time low of 198 on November 13th.

  9. Specifically, the rate of growth of electricity consumption per wage earner was computed using U.S. Bureau of the Census, Annual Survey of Manufactures data on electric horsepower (installed and purchased) by industry as well as the corresponding number of wage earners. For example, electricity use per worker in the tobacco industry (American Tobacco) increased by 14%, while it increased by 392% in the oil refining industry (Texas Corporation).

References

  • Beaudreau BC (1996) Mass production, the stock market crash, and the great depression: the macroeconomics of electrification. Greenwood Press, Westport

    Google Scholar 

  • Beaudreau, Bernard C (2005) Making sense of Smoot-Hawley: technology and tariffs. iUniverse, New York

  • Beaudreau, Bernard C (2014) Discriminating between tariff bill-based theories of the stock market crash using event study data. Essays in Economic and Business History 32:80–99

  • Binder JJ (1985) Measuring the effects of regulation with stock price data. RAND J Econ 16:167–183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeLong JB, Shleifer A (1991) The stock market bubble of 1929: evidence from closed-end funds. J Econ Hist 52(3):675–700

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher I (1930) The stock market crash and after. Macmillan, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • French K (2015) Fama-French Three-Factor CRSP Data-Daily. http://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/facultry/ken.french/data_library.html. Accessed 20 April 2016

  • Gordon R (2004) Five puzzles in the behavior of productivity, investment and innovation. In: Lopez-Claros A, Sala-i-Martin X (eds) The Global Competitiveness Report 2003–2004. Oxford University Press, New York

  • Kaplan E (1996) American Trade Policy, 1923–1995: (Contributions in Economics and Economic History). Greenwood Press, Westport

    Google Scholar 

  • McGrattan E, Prescott E (2004) The 1929 stock market: Irving fisher was right. Int Econ Rev 45(4):9911009

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merrill MR (1990) Reed Smoot: apostle in politics. Utah State Press, Logan

    Google Scholar 

  • Nye D (1990) Electrifying America social meanings of a new technology, 1880–1940. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Rappoport P, White E (1993) Was their a bubble in the 1929 stock market? J Econ Hist 53(3):549–574

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rappoport P, White E (1994) Was the crash of 1929 expected? Am Econ Rev 84(1):271–281

    Google Scholar 

  • Shiller R (1981) Do stock prices move too much to be justified by subsequent changes in dividends? Am Econ Rev 71(3):421–436

    Google Scholar 

  • Wanniski J (1976) The way the world works. Simon and Schuster, New York

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Bernard C. Beaudreau.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Beaudreau, B.C. Electrification, the Smoot-Hawley tariff bill and the stock market boom and crash of 1929: evidence from longitudinal data. J Econ Finan 42, 631–650 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12197-017-9418-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12197-017-9418-6

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation