Abstract
Money laundering is not a victimless crime. Under certain circumstances, it may lead to significant criminal violence. We analyze the specific case of money laundering in local economies. Criminal organizations invest dirty money in legal local businesses, which may lead to short-term improvements in the economy that benefit the population. Authorities with access to local information may (purposely) fail to report suspicious economic activities to specialized agencies in charge of money laundering because it is politically and economically convenient. The economic windfall generated from illicit money can eventually attract additional criminal organizations to the community, or may fragment the dominant criminal organization, endogenously increasing violence. The violence generated in no way compensates the previous economic growth. We develop theoretical insights on the conditions under which this mechanism exists, and empirically test its incidence and the magnitude of its effects, using Mexican municipalities as units of analysis.
This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.

Notes
See https://www.unodc.org/unodc/en/money-laundering/index.html?ref=menuside. Interpol’s definition is similar, see https://www.interpol.int/Crimes/Financial-crime/Money-laundering
See the UNODC assessment’s here: https://www.unodc.org/unodc/en/money-laundering/globalization.html
It is estimated that a quarter of Mexico’s GDP comes from informal activities. See the International Labor Organization’s Notes on Formalization in Mexico: https://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/%2D%2D-ed_emp/documents/meetingdocument/wcms_433784.pdf
See FATF and GAFILAT 2018 for a detailed description on Mexico’s money laundering institutions.
2014 is the latest year available (https://www.inegi.org.mx/app/saic/).
INEGI census data (https://inegi.org.mx/datos/?init=2).
This case, however, was dismissed because of procedural misconducts. See https://www.reuters.com/article/us-mexico-mayor/mayor-of-mexico-resort-arrested-for-drug-gang-ties-idUSTRE64P5ST20100526
The complete regression output is in Appendix A.
See the FBI report: https://ucr.fbi.gov/crime-in-the-u.s/2018/crime-in-the-u.s.-2018/tables/table-16
Further details on federal contributions to municipalities can be found here: http://hacienda.gob.mx/ApartadosHaciendaParaTodos/aportaciones/28/pdf/2.1.pdf
References
Albanese JS (2014) The Italian-American mafia. In: Paoli L (ed) The Oxford handbook of organized crime. Oxford University Press, Oxford, UK, pp 142–158
Beck N, Katz JN (1995) What to do (and not to do) with time-series cross-section data. Am Polit Sci Rev 89(3):634–647
Behrens T (2015) Lift-off for Mexico? Crime and finance in money laundering governance structures. J Money Laundering Control 18(1):17–33
Calderón G, Robles G, Díaz-Cayeros A, Magaloni B (2015a) The beheading of criminal organizations and the dynamics of violence in Mexico. J Confl Resolut 59(8):1455–1485
Calderón G, Magaloni B, Robles G (2015b) The economic consequences of drug trafficking violence in Mexico. IDB-WP-426 and FSI, Stanford University. Available at: https://go.aws/2XwRGgm [Accessed June 15, 2018]
El Siwi Y (2018) Mafia, money-laundering and the Battle against criminal capital: the Italian case. J Money Laundering Control 21(2):124–133
Ering SO (2011) Trans-border crime and its socio-economic impact on developing economies. J Soc Soc Anthropol 2(2):73–80
Fajnzylber P, Lederman D, Loayza N (2002) What causes violent crime? Eur Econ Rev 46:1323–1357
Fearon JD, Laitin DD (2003) Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War. Am Polit Sci Rev 97(1):75–90
Ferwerda J (2009) The economics of crime and money laundering: does anti-money laundering policy reduce crime? Rev Law Econ 5(2):903–929
Ferwerda J (2013) The effects of money laundering. In: Unger B, Van der Linde D (eds) Research handbook on money laundering. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, UK, pp 35–46
Financial Action Task Force and Financial Action Task Force of Latin America (2018) Anti-money laundering and counter-terrorist financing measures. FATF and GAFILAT, Mexico. Paris. Available at, p 2018 https://www.fatf-gafi.org/media/fatf/documents/reports/mer4/MER-Mexico-2018.pdf [
Fituni LL (1998) Russia: organised crime and money laundering. J Money Laund Control 1(4):360–373
Flores-Macías G (2018) The consequences of militarizing anti-drug efforts for state capacity in Latin America: evidence from Mexico. Comp Politics 51(1):1–20
Jadoon A, Milton D (2019) Strength from the shadows? How Shadow Economies Affect Terrorist Activities Studies in Conflict & Terrorism https://doi.org/10.1080/1057610X.2019.1678880 [Accessed October 29, 2019]
Jaitman L (ed) (2015) The welfare costs of crime and violence in Latin America and the Caribbean. Interamerican Development Bank, Washington, DC Available at: https://publications.iadb.org/en/welfare-costs-crime-and-violence-latin-america-and-caribbean [Accessed January 18, 2018]
Kennedy A (2005) Dead fish across the trail: illustrations of money laundering methods. J Money Laundering Control 8(4):305–319
Levi M, Dakolias M, Greenberg T (2007) Money laundering and corruption. In: Pradhan S (ed) Campos JE. The Many Faces of Corruption Tracking Vulnerabilities at the Sector Level. Washington, The World Bank, Washington, pp 389–426
Magaloni B, Díaz-Cayeros A, Robles Peiro G, Matanock A, Romero V (2020) Living in fear: the dynamics of extortion in Mexico’s drug war. Comp Pol Stud 53(7):1124–1174
Markovska A, Adams N (2015) Political corruption and money laundering: lessons from Nigeria. J Money Laundering Control 18(2):169–181
Masciandaro D (2005) False and reluctant friends? National Money Laundering Regulation, international compliance and non-cooperative countries. Eur J Law Econ 20(1):17–30
Mattiace S, Ley S, Trejo G (2019) Indigenous resistance to criminal governance: why regional ethnic autonomy institutions protect communities from Narco rule in Mexico. Lat Am Res Rev 54(1):181–200
Mitsilegas V, Gilmore B (2007) The EU legislative framework against money laundering and terrorist finance: a critical analysis in the light of evolving global standards. Int Comp Law Q 56(1):119–140
Olson M (1993) Dictatorship, democracy, and development. Am Polit Sci Rev 87(3):567–576
Osorio J (2015) Contagion of drug violence: Spatio-temporal dynamics of the Mexican war on drugs journal of conflict resolution. Spec Issue Mex Drug Violence 59(8):1403–1432
Osorio Machado L (2002) Drug trafficking and money laundering in the Amazon region. Geoeconomic and Geopolitical Effects. Final Report MOST-UNESCO International Research Project. On the Economic and Social Transformations Connected with the International Drug Problem. Paris: UNESCO/MOST. Available at: https://bit.ly/371OfBd [Accessed November 11, 2019]
Ospina-Velasco J (2003) Combating money laundering and smuggling in Colombia. J Financial Crime 10(2):153–156
Phillips BJ (2015) How does leadership decapitation affect violence? The case of drug trafficking organizations in Mexico. J Polit 77(2):324–336
Ponce A (2019) Violence and electoral competition: criminal organizations and municipal candidates in Mexico. Trends Organized Crime 22:231–254
Ríos V (2013) Why did Mexico become so violent? A self-reinforcing violent equilibrium caused by competition and enforcement. Trends Organized Crime 16(2):138–155
Safdari A, Nurani MS, Aghajani K, Abdollahian F (2015) Social impact of money laundering. Asian J Res Social Sci Humanit 5(8):173–188
Schneider S (2004) Organized crime, money laundering, and the real estate market in Canada. J Prop Res 21(2):99–118
Schneider F (2010) Turnover of organized crime and money laundering: some preliminary empirical findings. Public Choice 144(3–4):473–486
Soares RR (2004) Development, crime and punishment: accounting for the international differences in crime rates. J Dev Econ 73(1):155–184
Soares RR, Naritomi J (2010) Understanding high crime rates in Latin America: the role of social and policy factors. In: Di Tella R, Edwards S, Schargrodsky E (eds) The economics of crime: lessons for and from Latin America. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 19–55
Tupman B, Zabyelina Y, Markovska A, Adams N (2015) Political corruption and money laundering: lessons from Nigeria. J Money Laundering Control 18(2):169–181
United Nations Office on Drugs and Crime (2019) Global study on homicide 2019. UNODC, Vienna. Available at: https://www.unodc.org/unodc/en/data-and-analysis/global-study-on-homicide.html [Accessed January 12, 2019]
Vaithilingam S, Nair M (2007) Factors affecting money laundering: lesson for developing countries. J Money Laundering Control 10(3):352–366
Zagaris B (2004) The merging of the anti-money laundering and counter-terrorism financial enforcement regimes after September 11, 2001. Berkeley J Int Law 22:123–158
Funding
The author declares that no funding was provided for this project.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Ethics declarations
Conflict of interest
The author declares that he has no conflict of interest.
Ethics approval
This article’s research does not involve human participants, their data or biological material, and/or animals. Therefore, it does not require ethics approval in this respect.
Consent to participate
This article’s research does not involve human subjects; therefore, no consent to participate is required.
Consent to publish
This article’s research does not involve human subjects; therefore, no consent to publish is required.
Additional information
Publisher’s note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Appendices
Appendices
Appendix 1 – Instrumental variables (first stage estimation)
Model A1
Dependent variable: Real per capita Local revenue | |
---|---|
Human Development Index | 900.2*** |
(29.55) | |
Urban | 52.23*** |
(3.449) | |
Public investment (t-1) | 0.0298*** |
(0.00197) | |
Constant | −634.1*** |
(22.55) | |
N | 49,136 |
Groups | 2430 |
Observations per group: | |
Min | 1 |
Avg | 20.2 |
Max | 27 |
R-sq | 0.102 |
Model A2 – Placebo regression
Dependent variable: Federal contributions | |
---|---|
Human Development Index | 186.7** |
(83.81) | |
Urban | −380.0*** |
(39.20) | |
Public investment (t-1) | 0.6506*** |
(0.02465) | |
Constant | 833.6*** |
(84.85) | |
N | 38,169 |
Groups | 2439 |
Observations per group: | |
Min | 1 |
Avg | 15.7 |
Max | 27 |
R-sq | 0.358 |
Appendix 2 – Summary statistics
Appendix 3 – Robustness tests
-
a)
Non-fixed effects
Dependent variable: Homicide rate per 100,000 habitants
Model 1 | Model C1 | Model C2 | Model C3 | |
---|---|---|---|---|
With state and year FE | Without state and year FE | Without year FE | Without state fixed effects | |
Positive economic shock (t) | −6.228*** | −2.478 | −2.466* | −6.011*** |
(1.510) | (1.541) | (1.486) | (1.565) | |
Positive economic shock (t-1) | −1.736 | −0.0963 | 0.0512 | −1.757 |
(1.772) | (1.837) | (1.775) | (1.830) | |
Positive economic shock (t-2) | 2.992 | 3.505* | 3.762* | 2.897 |
(1.953) | (2.029) | (1.986) | (1.995) | |
Positive economic shock (t-3) | 6.550*** | 6.994*** | 7.604*** | 6.150*** |
(2.032) | (2.085) | (2.066) | (2.051) | |
Population log | 0.815*** | 0.329** | 0.758*** | 0.379*** |
(0.137) | (0.142) | (0.140) | (0.140) | |
Distance to Northern Border | 0.00002*** | −0.000009*** | 0.00002*** | −0.00001*** |
(0.000003) | (0.000001) | (0.000003) | (0.000001) | |
Human Development Index | −73.54*** | −59.96*** | −51.46*** | −81.75*** |
(3.942) | (3.283) | (3.139) | (4.044) | |
Indigenous population | −0.0714*** | −0.0951*** | −0.0460*** | −0.127*** |
(0.009) | (0.008) | (0.009) | (0.009) | |
Municipal election | −0.202 | 0.0172 | −0.0996 | −0.0361 |
(0.332) | (0.365) | (0.341) | (0.358) | |
Mountainous terrain | 0.0295*** | 0.0333*** | 0.0360*** | 0.0275*** |
(0.00404) | (0.00365) | (0.00407) | (0.00365) | |
Constant | 47.60*** | 66.30*** | 28.88*** | 82.74*** |
(3.651) | (3.271) | (3.231) | (3.654) | |
State fixed effects | Yes | No | Yes | No |
Year fixed effects | Yes | No | No | Yes |
N | 29,784 | 29,784 | 29,784 | 29,784 |
Groups | 2221 | 2221 | 2221 | 2221 |
Observations per group: | ||||
Min | 1 | 1 | 1 | 1 |
Avg | 13.4 | 13.4 | 13.4 | 13.4 |
Max | 23 | 23 | 23 | 23 |
Wald chi2(62) | 6486.87 | 566.30 | 6351.43 | 1174.60 |
Prob > chi2 | 0.0000 | 0.0000 | 0.0000 | 0.0000 |
R-sq | 0.183 | 0.030 | 0.1542 | 0.0588 |
-
b)
Different lagged periods
Dependent variable: Homicide rate per 100,000 habitants
Model 1 | Model C4 | Model C5 | Model C6 | Model C7 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
3 lags | 1 lag | 2 lags | 4 lags | 5 lags | |
Positive economic shock (t) | −6.228*** | −5.457*** | −5.786*** | −6.597*** | −6.011*** |
(1.510) | (1.492) | (1.493) | (1.545) | (1.603) | |
Positive economic shock (t-1) | −1.736 | −0.900 | −1.080 | −1.573 | −1.512 |
(1.772) | (1.754) | (1.765) | (1.923) | (1.818) | |
Positive economic shock (t-2) | 2.992 | 3.382* | 2.495 | 1.894 | |
(1.953) | (1.940) | (2.143) | (2.233) | ||
Positive economic shock (t-3) | 6.550*** | 6.595*** | 6.094** | ||
(2.032) | (2.263) | (2.415) | |||
Positive economic shock (t-4) | 2.025 | 0.952 | |||
(2.432) | (2.627) | ||||
Positive economic shock (t-5) | 3.972 | ||||
(2.854) | |||||
Population log | 0.815*** | 0.812*** | 0.812*** | 0.739*** | 0.709*** |
(0.137) | (0.137) | (0.137) | (0.149) | (0.158) | |
Distance to Northern Border | 0.00002*** | 0.00002*** | 0.00002*** | 0.00002*** | 0.00002*** |
(0.000003) | (0.000003) | (0.000003) | (0.000004) | (0.000004) | |
Human Development Index | −73.54*** | −73.02*** | −73.20*** | −72.76*** | −76.02*** |
(3.942) | (3.937) | (3.944) | (4.576) | (5.126) | |
Indigenous population | −0.0714*** | −0.0714*** | −0.0714*** | −0.0714*** | −0.0797*** |
(0.00914) | (0.00915) | (0.00914) | (0.0102) | (0.0109) | |
Municipal election | −0.202 | −0.205 | −0.202 | −0.229 | −0.374 |
(0.332) | (0.332) | (0.332) | (0.363) | (0.385) | |
Mountainous terrain Constant | 0.0295*** | 0.0296*** | 0.0296*** | 0.0281*** | 0.0269*** |
(0.00404) | (0.00404) | (0.00404) | (0.00437) | (0.00468) | |
47.60*** | 47.22*** | 47.36*** | 46.77*** | 50.74*** | |
(3.651) | (3.644) | (3.651) | (4.193) | (4.712) | |
State fixed effects | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Year fixed effects | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
N | 29,784 | 29,784 | 29,784 | 26,575 | 23,702 |
Groups | 2221 | 2221 | 2221 | 2151 | 2046 |
Observations per group: | |||||
Min | 1 | 1 | 1 | 1 | 1 |
Avg | 13.4 | 13.4 | 13.4 | 12.4 | 11.6 |
Max | 23 | 23 | 23 | 22 | 21 |
Wald chi2(62) | 6486.87 | 6491.48 | 6490.28 | 5742.98 | 5206.58 |
Prob > chi2 | 0.0000 | 0.0000 | 0.0000 | 0.0000 | 0.0000 |
R-sq | 0.183 | 0.182 | 0.182 | 0.186 | 0.194 |
-
c)
Different shock thresholds
Dependent variable: Homicide rate per 100,000 habitants
Model 1 | Model C8 | Model C9 | |
---|---|---|---|
1 SD | 2 SD | 3 SD | |
Positive economic shock (t) | −6.228*** | −13.46*** | −7.048** |
(1.510) | (2.725) | (3.130) | |
Positive economic shock (t-1) | −1.736 | −4.863 | −0.455 |
(1.772) | (3.431) | (2.938) | |
Positive economic shock (t-2) | 2.992 | 4.836 | 5.040 |
(1.953) | (3.768) | (3.106) | |
Positive economic shock (t-3) | 6.550*** | 8.006** | 3.823 |
(2.032) | (3.576) | (3.559) | |
Population log | 0.815*** | 0.816*** | 0.806*** |
(0.137) | (0.137) | (0.137) | |
Distance to Northern Border | 0.00002*** | 0.00002*** | 0.00002*** |
(0.000003) | (0.000003) | (0.000003) | |
Human Development Index | −73.54*** | −75.34*** | −71.94*** |
(3.942) | (3.953) | (3.915) | |
Indigenous population | −0.0714*** | −0.0744*** | −0.0689*** |
(0.00914) | (0.00911) | (0.00915) | |
Municipal election | −0.202 | −0.200 | −0.198 |
(0.332) | (0.332) | (0.332) | |
Mountainous terrain | 0.0295*** | 0.0292*** | 0.0301*** |
(0.00404) | (0.00405) | (0.00405) | |
Constant | 47.60*** | 49.13*** | 46.33*** |
(3.651) | (3.647) | (3.637) | |
State fixed effects | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Year fixed effects | Yes | Yes | Yes |
N | 29,784 | 29,784 | 29,784 |
Groups | 2221 | 2221 | 2221 |
Observations per group: | |||
Min | 1 | 1 | 1 |
Avg | 13.4 | 13.4 | 13.4 |
Max | 23 | 23 | 23 |
Wald chi2(62) | 6486.87 | 6492.63 | 6525.74 |
Prob > chi2 | 0.0000 | 0.0000 | 0.0000 |
R-sq | 0.183 | 0.183 | 0.182 |
-
d)
Dependent variable: Homicide rate for males 15–39 years
Model 1 | Model C10 | |
---|---|---|
DV: Homicide rate general population | DV: Homicide rate males 15–39 years | |
Positive economic shock (t) | −6.228*** | −12.860*** |
(1.510) | (2.407) | |
Positive economic shock (t-1) | −1.736 | −3.136 |
(1.772) | (2.595) | |
Positive economic shock (t-2) | 2.992 | 4.679* |
(1.953) | (2.821) | |
Positive economic shock (t-3) | 6.550*** | 10.64*** |
(2.032) | (3.053) | |
Population | 0.815*** | 0.947*** |
(0.137) | (0.247) | |
Distance to N. Border | 0.00002*** | 0.00004*** |
(0.000003) | (0.000005) | |
Human Dev. Index | −73.54*** | −130.3*** |
(3.942) | (6.682) | |
Indigenous population | −0.0714*** | −0.112*** |
(0.00914) | (−0.016) | |
Municipal election | −0.202 | −0.456 |
(0.332) | (0.597) | |
Mountainous terrain | 0.0295*** | 0.0566*** |
(0.00404) | (0.00725) | |
Constant | 47.60*** | 88.12*** |
(3.651) | (5.994) | |
State fixed effects | Yes | Yes |
Year fixed effects | Yes | Yes |
N | 29,784 | 29,585 |
Groups | 2221 | 2211 |
Observations per group: | ||
Min | 1 | 1 |
Avg | 13.4 | 13.4 |
Max | 23 | 23 |
Wald chi2(62) | 6486.87 | 5442.41 |
Prob > chi2 | 0.0000 | 0.0000 |
R-sq | 0.183 | 0.173 |
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Romero, V. Bloody investment: misaligned incentives, money laundering and violence. Trends Organ Crim 25, 8–36 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12117-020-09391-x
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12117-020-09391-x
Keywords
- Money laundering
- Violence
- Criminal organizations
- Corruption
- Homicide