Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Inequality, Economic Development, and Democratization

  • Published:
Studies in Comparative International Development Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Although multiple theories suggest that economic development and inequality somehow affect democratization, these claims have received only limited empirical support. I contend that much of the confusion stems from the implicit assumption held by the literature that development and inequality affect democratization independently of one another. In this paper, I argue that the effect of income distribution on democratization is in fact contingent on the income level: in middle-income countries inequality fosters democratization; in rich countries, however, it harms democratization. Using a data set covering almost all autocracies between 1960 and 2007, I find evidence consistent with my hypothesis.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. One partial exception is Reenock, Bernhard, and Sobek (2007) who show that deprivation only destabilizes middle-income democracies. However, this study looks at democratic breakdowns—not democratization—and focuses on deprivation, not inequality. Przeworski (2006) argues that inequality is more destabilizing in poor democracies. Again, Przeworski (2006) does not look at the question of democratization, and factors that affect democratization and consolidation are often different (e.g., Przeworski et al. 2000). Boix (2003) argues that the effect of inequality depends on asset mobility—even though his empirical tests do not account for a conditional relationship—which depends partially on development.

  2. In poor countries, inequality is not even significantly related to deprivation (Reenock, Bernhard and Sobek 2007).

  3. Autocracies are assumed to represent the interests of the capital class, and democracies those of the median voter who is a member of the labor class.

  4. There are also other theories on the relationship between inequality and democratization that do not rely on the role of redistribution, such as that of Ansell and Samuels (2010, 2013, 2014). The work of Ansell and Samuels is discussed in more detail below.

  5. These authors, however, do not exclusively rely on the redistribution mechanism.

  6. For studies finding no relationships see Bollen and Jackman (1985); Papaionannou and Siourounis (2005); Houle (2009, 2013), a negative relationship see Muller (1988), (1995); Boix and Stokes (2003); Boix (2003), a positive relationship see Ansell and Samuels (2010, 2014); Midlarsky (1992), and an inverted U-shaped relationship see Burkhart (1997).

  7. Cases in which mass mobilization occurred but did not oppose groups from different social classes are categorized as non-distributive conflict transitions (e.g., Ukraine 1991). These transitions clearly do not provide support for the causal mechanisms of inequality theories.

  8. This cut-off point as well as that between intermediate and high income levels ($8,000) have been estimated in the regressions reported below (see model 2 of Table 3).

  9. This argument is consistent with the results of Fearon and Laitin (2003), according to which GDP per capita decreases the likelihood of civil war by improving the ability of the state to repress insurgents.

  10. Note that my argument does not imply that the observed level of violence should be higher in rich autocracies, or that autocracies at low/middle levels of development should be less repressive. While, for example, the DRC has experienced more state violence than Singapore throughout its history, one could make the argument that regime outsiders could more easily dislodge the regime in the former than in the latter.

  11. In Poland, for example, while the Solidarity movement was clearly based on the industrial working class (Haggard, Kaufman and Teo 2012), its aim was to replace communism with capitalism (which eventually led to an increase in inequality). Similarly, the transition to democracy in South Korea has usually been perceived as caused by an increase in income that led to demands for political rights rather than because the masses wanted more redistribution (Huntington 1991; Inglehart and Welzel 2009). Although mass mobilization did play a crucial role, it involved cross-class mobilization as well as elements of the middle class (Haggard, Kaufman and Teo 2012). Lastly, despite its relatively high per capita income, Suriname is heavily aid-dependent. Although class mobilization did play a central role during the transition, so did international actors, in particular the Netherlands and the United States that suspended all aid following massive military repression (Haggard, Kaufman and Teo 2012).

  12. See also (Calhoun 1982; Feierabend et al. 1969; Haas and Stack 1983, 1967, 2007, 1989).

  13. My argument is also consistent with the findings of Reenock, Bernhard and Sobek (2007), who show that deprivation destabilizes middle income democracies, but not rich or poor ones. Although these authors are primarily interested in democracies, not autocracies, their findings directly connect to mine, since they imply that distributional issues are most destabilizing at middling GDP per capita levels.

  14. The absence of distributional conflict during a transition does not necessarily imply that inequality had no role in explaining why the transition occurred. Since, everything else being equal, the different factions of the elites have more to lose economically when inequality between the elites (as a whole) and the masses is large, transitions through non-distributive conflict may be facilitated by low levels of inequality.

  15. None of these averages are statistically significantly different from one another.

  16. Houle (2009) argues that these predictions by Acemoglu and Robinson (2006) are driven by the assumption that the cost of repression for the elites is binary, i.e., (1) the elites either repress or do not repress (in which case the cost of maintaining an autocracy is zero); and (2) when they repress the cost of repression does not depend on inequality.

  17. Summary statistics are provided in Table A1 of the online appendix.

  18. Acemoglu and Robinson (2006) and Przeworski et al. (2000) use the version of Rodrik (1999).

  19. In the main analysis, I use the version of Houle (Forthcoming) who imputes values for nearly all countries. As shown in section 3 of the Online Appendix, my results are robust to the use of the original data of Ortega and Rodriguez (2006) (see Table A2).

  20. Freeman and Quinn (2012) have recently pointed to some problems with the use of capital shares. I address these issues in section 1 of the Online Appendix and provide more information on capital shares and the problems related to the use of its main alternatives.

  21. I use Amelia II to impute missing values. See section 3 of the Online Appendix for detail.

  22. Soifer’s (2013) indicator takes the value one if a state has administrated a census within the last 10 (rather than 12) years. However, when I use 10 years, the proportion of countries that lack extractive capacity is very high (27.65 %). This proportion drops to 20.03 % when I use 12 years. As explained below, I expect only the very poorest countries to completely lack the capacity to redistribute. Hanson (2015) also uses the administration of a census to measure state capacity.

  23. The COW dataset covers security forces that can also be used to combat foreign armies.

  24. Oil is taken from Haber and Menaldo (2011) and Muslim and Ethnic Fractionization from Przeworski et al. (2000).

  25. These are calculated using the codes provided by Matt Golder (https://files.nyu.edu/mrg217/public/interaction3.pdf). Control variables are set at their mean or median. In nonlinear models, the marginal effect of a variable varies with its level. Therefore, Fig. 2 evaluates the marginal effect of capital share at its mean. I also evaluated the marginal effect of capital share across its full range (minimum and maximum values) using other marginal effects plots. The shape of the relationship is unchanged (available upon request).

  26. Among the very poorest countries (GDP per capita below $400), the relationship is positive. However, very few countries are that poor. In fact, there has been only one democratization among such countries in the sample (Burundi 2005). Moreover, as shown in Fig. 3, even in countries with a GDP per capita as low as $600, there is actually no relationship between inequality and democratization.

  27. Observations from countries that remained authoritarian during the full period (e.g., Saudi Arabia) and years during which no autocracy within the sample democratized (e.g., 1964) are dropped.

  28. In section 6 of the Online Appendix, I test whether democratization in the future affects inequality and income levels today (Tables A11 and A12). Results show that it does not. This is essentially a test of whether the prospect of democratization affects inequality and income, which is among the main paths through which they could be endogenous to democratization.

  29. Data on financial openness is from Freeman and Quinn (2012), agricultural share of GDP from the World Bank, population from Haber and Menaldo (2011), and those on the other variables from Przeworski et al. (2000).

  30. Boix (2003) makes the argument that the effect of inequality on democratization may be contingent on capital mobility, although his estimations do not account for a conditional effect. Therefore, I run models in which the effect of inequality is conditioned by the agricultural share of GDP (Table A16).

References

  • Acemoglu D, Robinson JA. Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press; 2006.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Johnson S, Robinson JA, Yared P. Income and democracy. Amer Econ Rev. 2008;98(3):808–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ahlquist JS, Wibbels E. Riding the wave: world trade and factor-based models of democratization. Amer J Polit Sci. 2012;56(2):447–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ai C, Norton E. Interaction terms in logit and probit models. Econ Lett. 2003;80:123–9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Albertus M, Menaldo V. Coercive capacity and the prospects for democratization. Compar Polit. 2012;44(2):151–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ansell B, Samuels D. Inequality and democratization: a contractarian approach. Comp. Polit Stud. 2010;20(10):1–32.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ansell B, Samuels D. Rethinking inequality and democratization: how inequality divides elites and underpins regime change. APSA-Comp. Democrat Newslett. 2013;11(3):8–11.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ansell B, Samuels D. Inequality and democratization: an elite-competition approach. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2014.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bellin E. The robustness of authoritarianism in the Middle East. Comp. Polit. 2004;36:139–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley T, Persson T. The causes and consequences of development clusters: state capacity, peace, and income. Ann Rev Econ. 2014;6:927–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, Bond S. Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. J Economet. 1998;87:115–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boix C. Democracy and redistribution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2003.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Boix C. RMDs. APSA-Comp. Democrat Newslett. 2013;11(3):12–5.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boix C, Miller MK, Rosato S. A complete data set of political regimes, 1800-2007. Comparative Polit Stud. 2013;46(12):1523–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boix C, Stokes SC. Endogenous democratization. World Polit. 2003;55(4): 517–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bollen KA, Jackman RW. Political democracy and the size distribution of income. Amer Sociologic Rev. 1985;50(4):438–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brambor T, Clark WR, Golder M. Understanding interaction models: improving empirical analyses. Polit Anal. 2006;14:63–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buhaug H. Relative capability and rebel objective in Civil War. J Peace Res. 2006;43(6):691–708.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buhaug H. Dude, where’s my conflict? LSG, relative strength, and the location of Civil War. Conflict Manag Peace Sci. 2010;27(2):107–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burkhart RE. Comparative democracy and income distribution: shape and direction of the causal arrow. J Polit. 1997;59(1):148–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calhoun C. The Question Of Class Struggle. Chicago: University of Chicago Press; 1982.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cheibub J, Gandhi J, Vreeland J. Democracy and dictatorship revisited. Public Choice. 2010;143(1–2):67–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dahl RA. Polyarchy, participation and opposition. New Haven: Yale University Press; 1971.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deininger K, Squire L. A new data set measuring income inequality. World Bank Econ Rev. 1996;10(3):565–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunning T. Crude democracy: natural resource wealth and political regimes. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2008.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Fearon JD, Laitin DD. Ethnicity, insurgency and Civil War. Amer Polit Sci Rev. 2003;97(1):75–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feierabend ID, Feierabend RL, Nesvold BA. Social change and political violence: cross-national patterns. Violence in America: historical and comparative perspectives. In: Graham HD and Gurr TR, editors. New York: Signet; 1969.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fortin-Rittberger J. Exploring the relationship between infrastructural and coercive state capacity. Democratization. 2014;21(7):1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman JR, Quinn DP. The economic origins of democracy reconsidered. Amer Politi Sci Rev. 2012;106:58–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galbraith JK. Inequality and instability: a study of the world economy just before the great crisis. New York: Oxford University Press; 2012.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gibler D, Miller S. External territorial threat, state capacity, and Civil War. J Peace Res. 2014;51(5):634–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gould W, Pitblado JS, Sribney W. 2006. Maximum likelihood estimation with stata. Stata Press.

  • Haber S, Menaldo V. Do natural resources fuel authoritarianism? A reappraisal of the resource curse. Amer Polit Sci Rev. 2011;105(1):1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haas A, Stack S. Economic development and strikes: a comparative analysis. Sociol Q. 1983;24(1):43–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haggard S, Kaufman RR. Inequality and regime change: democratic transitions and the stability of democratic rule. Amer Polit Sci Rev. 2012;106:495–516.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haggard S, Kaufman RR, Teo T. 2012. Distributive conflict and regime change. A qualitative data set. (accessed October 2012).

  • Haggard S, Kaufman RR, Teo T. Inequality and regime change: the role of distributive conflict. APSA-Comp Democrat Newslett. 2013;11(3):4–7.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanson J. Democracy and state capacity: complements or substitutes? Stud Comp Int Develop. 2015;50:304–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanson J, Sigman Rl. Leviathan’s latent dimensions: measuring state capacity for comparative political research. Unpublished Manuscript: University of Michigan, and Syracruse University; 2013.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heid B, Langer J, Larch M. Income and democracy: evidence from system GMM estimates. Econ Lett. 2012;116(2):166–9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hendrix CS. Measuring state capacity: theoretical and empirical implications for the study of civil conflict. J Peace Res. 2010;47(3):273–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Houle C. Inequality and democracy: why inequality harms consolidation but does not affect democratization. World Polit. 2009;61(4):589–622.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Houle C. Inequality, democratization and democratic consolidation 2013. APSA-Comp Democrat Newslett. 2013;11(3):21–24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Houle C. Does inequality harm economic development and democracy? Accounting for mssing values, non-comparable observations and endogeneity. The Oxford handbook of the politics of international development. In: Lancaster C and van de Walle N, editors. Oxford: Oxford University Press; Forthcoming.

  • Huntington S. Political order in changing societies. New Haven and London: Yale University Press; 1968.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huntington S. The third wave: democratization in the late twentieth century. Norman: University of Oklahoma Press; 1991.

    Google Scholar 

  • Inglehart R, Welzel C. 2009. How development leads to democracy? What we know about modernization. Foreign affairs. March/April.

  • Kennedy R. The contradiction of modernization: a conditional model of endogenous democratization. J Polit. 2010;72(03):785–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lieberman E. Taxation data as indicators of state-society relations: possibilities and pitfalls in cross-national research. Stud Comp Int Develop. 2002;36(4):89–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lipset SM. Some social requisites of democracy: economic development and political legitimacy. Amer Polit Sci Rev. 1959;53(1):69–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meltzer AH, Richard SF. A rational theory of the size of government. J Polit Econ. 1981;89(5):914–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Midlarsky MI. The origins of democracy in agrarian society: land inequality and political rights. J Conflict Resol. 1992;36(3):454–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller MK. Economic development, violent leader removal, and democratization. Amer J Polit Sci. 2012;56(4):1002–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Muller EN. Democracy, economic development, and income inequality. Amer Sociol Rev. 1988;53(1):50–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Muller EN. Economic determinants of democracy. Amer Sociol Rev. 1995;60(6): 966–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ortega D, Rodriguez F. 2006. Are capital shares higher in poor countries? Evidence from industrial surveys. Unpublished Manuscript, Corporacin Andina de Fomento (CAF) and IESA, and Wesleyan University.

  • Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices. ND. Penn World Tables. Available from https://pwt.sas.upenn.edu/, access October, 2012.

  • Papaionannou E, Siourounis G. 2005. Economic and Social Factors Driving the Third Wave of Democratization. Manuscript, London Business School.

  • Przeworski A. Self-enforcing democracy. The Oxford handbook of political economy. In: Weingast BR and Wittman DA, editors. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 2006.

    Google Scholar 

  • Przeworski A, Alvarez ME, Cheibub JA, Limongi F. Democracy and development. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2000.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Reenock C, Bernhard M, Sobek D. Regressive socioeconomic distribution and democratic survival. Int Stud Q. 2007;51(3):677–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik D. Democracies pay higher wages. Q J Econ. 1999;114(3):707–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rostow WW. Guerilla warfare in underdeveloping areas. The Viet-Nam reader. In: Raskin MG and Fall BB, editors. Random House: New York; 1967.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scalapino RA. Democratizing dragons: South Korea and Taiwan. J Democr. 1993;4 (3):70–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slater D, Smith B, Nair G. Economic origins of democratic breakdown? The redistributive model and the post-colonial State. Perspect Polit. 2014;12(2):353–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Soifer H. State power and the economic origins of democracy. Stud Comp Int Develop. 2013;48(1):1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solt F. Standardizing the World income inequality database. Soc Sci Q. 2009; 90:231–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svolik M. The politics of authoritarian rule. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2012.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Tadjoeddin MZ, Murshed SM. Socio-economic determinants of everyday violence in Indonesia: an empirical investigation of javanese districts, 1994-2003. J Peace Res. 2007;44(6):689–709.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tilly C. Coercion, capital, and European States. Cambridge: Blackwell Press; 2001.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walter B. Building reputation: why governments fight some separatists but not others. Amer J Polit Sci. 2006;50(2):313–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • White JW. Economic development and sociopolitical unrest in nineteenth-century Japan. Econ Develop Cultural Change. 1989;37(2):231–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

Winner of the 2011 Kellogg/Notre Dame Award for best paper in comparative politics presented at the MPSA convention. Earlier versions of this paper were presented at the Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, Chicago, at the Annual Meeting of the International Political Economy Society, College Station TX, and at the Comparative Politics Workshop, University of Rochester. I gratefully acknowledge comments and suggestions from Alexandre Debs, Mark Fey, Jennifer Gandhi, Gretchen Helmke, Timothy Hicks, Tasos Kalandrakis, Mark A. Kayser, Jeremy Kedziora, G. Bingham Powell, Curtis Signorino, Randall Stone, Olesya Tkacheva, Jay Ulfelder, Milan Svolik and Jeffrey Weber. I am also grateful to Jonathan Hanson and Rachel Sigman, and Hillel Soifer for sharing data. I would also like thank Jessica Fortin for discussions on different measures of state capacity. All errors are mine.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Christian Houle.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

(PDF 830 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Houle, C. Inequality, Economic Development, and Democratization. St Comp Int Dev 51, 503–529 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-016-9220-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-016-9220-z

Keywords

Navigation