Skip to main content

The Rise of Rational Choice Theory as a Scientific/Intellectual Movement in Sociology

Abstract

How did Rational Choice Theory (RCT), traditionally rejected by sociologists for its economic individualism, rise rapidly in the 1980s and the 1990s to theoretical and institutional prominence within sociology? Drawing on Frickel and Gross’ (American Sociological Association, 70(2):204–232 2005) framework for the emergence of scientific/intellectual movements (SIMs), we argue that RCT rose to prominence in sociology in conjunction with: 1) high status actors’ criticism of the previously dominant paradigm, structural functionalism; 2) favorable structural conditions that provided entrepreneurial access to key resources; 3) proliferation through micromobilization contexts; and 4) the ability of those espousing RCT for sociology to draw on dominant cultural motifs outside of academia. The rise of RCT in American sociology provides a case study for how scientific/intellectual movements can find an audience in academic contexts that are predisposed to oppose them.

This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.

Notes

  1. While the RCT of the 1980s and 1990s represented a distinct theoretical moment in the history of social theorizing, it was not the first appearance of some of the premises of RCT within sociology. A number of early sociologists were trained as economists (Young 2009). Additionally, the exchange theory of George Homans incorporated RCT-like elements. A major emphasis of exchange theory was the claim that individuals rationally evaluated their interactions with others (Homans 1958). While Coleman (1993) notes that his version of RCT owed a primary debt to Gary Becker for its expansion into the explanation of social phenomena, Swedberg (1996:315) argued that Coleman’s RCT also benefited from the social exchange theory contributions of Homans and suggested that a presentation by Homans was the moment when Coleman was first introduced to rational choice theory.

  2. This steep rise may reflect game theory’s rational choice underpinning (e.g., as in the well-known “prisoner’s dilemma” game) and relevance to issues of major importance to political scientists, such as nuclear deterrence and electoral competition (von Neumann and Morgenstern 2004; Osbourne and Turner 2010; Powell 1990).

  3. By some measures, the rise of RCT was incomplete. Baron and Hannan (1994) found (via data from the Social Science Citation Index on citations to the American Economic Review (AER) and the Journal of Political Economy (JPE) in the American Journal of Sociology (AJS) and American Sociological Review (ASR)) that there was little increase in citation of economic work in sociology after the 1970s. However, the authors also note that, although sociologists were not necessarily citing economists more overall, they were citing the work of Gary Becker (whose important contributions to the rise of RCT in sociology in partnership with James Coleman we discuss later in the paper) more. Becker was the second-most cited economist in ASR and AJS in 1980 and the most cited from 1990 to 1991. He was also the most cited economist in the Annual Review of Sociology from 1989 to 1992.

  4. Both Frickel and Gross’ first proposition and Mullins’ normal stage in turn address Kuhn’s (2012) assertion that new theories, questions, and data can lead to a paradigm shift within an academic discipline.

  5. Indeed, C. Wright Mills, the father of modern conflict theory, critiqued the very notion of a “grand theory” as he criticized Parsons from a conflict theory via the sociological imagination.

  6. Some saw this multi-theoretical moment as redemptive for sociology, reinvigorating the field in a time of lower enrollments in sociology departments (Turner 2014).

  7. Although highly praised, Foundations of Social Theory was faced strong criticism for ignoring conceptual problems in macro-micro transitions (Gibbs 1990).

  8. Edward Laumann, e-mail correspondence, July 17, 2013.

  9. Edward Laumann, e-mail correspondence, July 17, 2013.

  10. This information was obtained from the program coordinator for governance and information systems at the American Sociological Association via e-mail message to the author on January 13, 2012.

  11. This information was confirmed via phone conversation with staff from the University of Chicago Press on July 21, 2016.

  12. Although previous presidents also reduced certain regulations, the scale was unprecedented under Reagan. Jimmy Carter rolled back regulations in certain areas (such as air transportation and banking) but increased health, safety, and environmental regulations (Roark et al. 2011). Similarly, Richard Nixon called for deregulation, but his appointees to regulatory commissions were more open to regulation, and he heavily regulated the energy industry with price and wage controls (Crain 2007).

  13. The greed of the 1980s, in some ways, validated Riesman and colleagues’ (1963) concerns about the role of consumerism in undermining traditional agents of socialization and Slater’s (1970) description of “people already weighted down with possessions acting as if every object they did not own were bread withheld from a hungry mouth.”

References

  • Allen, S. (2014). Television in the United States. Encyclopedia Britannica. http://www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/1513870/Television-in-the-United-States/283635/The-era-of-the-miniseries#toc283636. Accessed 12 Sept 2014.

  • Amadae, S. M. (2003). Rationalizing capitalist democracy: The cold war origins of rational choice liberalism. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • American Sociological Association (2016). Distinguished Scholarly Book ASA Award. http://cfd153.cfdynamics.com/about/awards/book.cfm. Accessed 21 July 2016.

  • American Sociological Association Section on Rationality and Society (2014). Cumulative listing of section officers: Rationality and society (33). https://docs.google.com/viewer?a=v&pid=sites&srcid=ZGVmYXVsdGRvbWFpbnxyYXRpb25hbGl0eWFuZHNvY2lldHlzZWN0aW9ufGd4OjJkMWNhYjBlMjJhNzJmYQ. Accesed 1 Sept 2015.

  • Appelrouth, S., & Edles, L. D. (2008). Classical and contemporary sociological theory: Text and readings. Thousand Oaks: Pine Forge Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Appleby, J. (2010). The relentless revolution: A history of capitalism. New York: W. W. Norton and Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bailey, K. D. (1991). Alternative procedures for Macrosociological theorizing. Quality & Quantity, 25, 37–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barnes, T. J., & Sheppard, E. (1992). Is there a place for the rational actor? A geographical critique of the rational choice paradigm. Economic Geography, 68(1), 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron, J. N., & Hannan, M. T. (1994). The impact of economics on contemporary sociology. Journal of Economic Literature, 32(3), 1111–1146.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1976). The economic approach to human behavior. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Black, M. (Ed.). (1961). The social theories of Talcott Parsons: a critical examination. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boudon, R. (1998). Limitations of rational choice theory. American Journal of Sociology, 104(3), 817–828.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowler, K. (2013). Blessed: a history of the American prosperity gospel. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd, W. L., Crowson, R. L., & Geel, Y. (1995). Rational choice theory and the politics of education. In D. H. Layton (Ed.), The study of educational politics (pp. 127–146) . Washington, DC: Falmer Press.Association Politics of Education, and Jay D. Scribner

    Google Scholar 

  • Busch, A. E. (2005). In P. Kengor & P. Schweizer (Eds.), The Reagan presidency: assessing the man and his legacy. Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, Inc..

    Google Scholar 

  • Business Week. (1983). Computer shock hits the office. Business Week, August 8, 46–49, 52–53.

  • Calhoun, C. (1998). Explanation in historical sociology: Narrative, general theory, and historically specific theory. American Journal of Sociology, 104(3), 846–871.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cave, R., (Ed.) (1983). Time Magazine. January 3, 1983: Cover.

  • Chai, S. (2001). Choosing an identity: a general model of preference and belief formation. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Chaves, M. (1995). On the rational choice approach to religion. Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion, 34(1), 98–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, J., (Ed.) (1996). James S. Coleman. London and Washington, D.C.: Palmer Press (Taylor & Francis Group).

  • Clarke, R. V. G., & Cornish, D. B. (Eds.). (1986). The reasoning criminal: rational choice perspectives on offending. New York: Springer-Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J. S. (1966). Individual interests and collective action. In G. Tullock (Ed.), Papers on non-market decision-making (pp. 49–62). Charlottesville: Thomas Jefferson Center for Political Economy, University of Virginia.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J. S. (1986). Social theory, social research, and a theory of action. The American Journal of Sociology, 91(6), 1309–1335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J. S. (1993). The impact of Gary Becker's work on sociology. Acta Sociologica, 36(3), 169–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J. S., & Fararo, T. J. (Eds.). (1992). Rational choice theory: Advocacy and critique. Thousand Oaks: SAGE.

    Google Scholar 

  • Collins, R. (1990). Conflict theory and the advance of macro-historical sociology. In G. Ritzer (Ed.), Frontiers of social theory: The new syntheses. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Collins, R. (1994). Four sociological traditions. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Computer History Museum. (2014a). Computers for Everybody. http://www.computerhistory.org/revolution/personal-computers/17/298. Accessed 16 Sept 2014.

  • Computer History Museum. (2014b). The IBM PC. http://www.computerhistory.org/revolution/personal-computers/17/301. Accessed 16 Sept 2014.

  • Computer History Museum. (2014c). What Was the First PC? http://www.computerhistory.org/revolution/personal-computers/17/297. Accessed 16 Sept 2014.

  • Cook, K. (1982). Network Structure from an exchange perspective. In N. Lin & P. Marsden (Eds.), Social Structure and network analysis (pp. 177–199). Beverly Hills: Sage Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cook, K. S., Emerson, R. M., Gillmore, M. R., & Yamagishi, T. (1983). The distribution of power in exchange networks: Theory and experimental results. American Journal of Sociology, 89(2), 275–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coons, J. (1978). Education by choice: the case for family control. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crain, A. (2007). Ford, Carter, and deregulation in the 1970s. Journal on Telecommunications & High Technology Law, 5, 413–447.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, K. (1959). The myth of functional analysis as a special method in sociology and anthropology. American Sociological Review, 24(6), 757–772.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demerath III, N. J. (1995). Rational paradigms, A-rational religion, and the debate over secularization. Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion, 34(1), 105–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dudar, H. (1979). Louis Rukeyser and his Socko stock-market show. Chicago Tribune Magazine, September 20, pp. 29-30, 35-37.

  • Eisenstadt, S. N., & Curelaru, M. (1976). The form of sociology: Paradigms and crises. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ellison, C. G. (1995). Rational choice explanations of individual religious behavior: Notes on the problem of social embeddedness. Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion, 34(1), 89–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elster, J. (1982). The case for methodological individualism. Theory and Society, 11(4), 453–482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Endlich, L. (2000). Goldman Sachs: The culture of success. New York: Touchstone.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feagin, J. R., Vera, H., & Ducey, K. (2016). Liberation sociology (3rd ed.). New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Folkenflik, D. (2013). Murdoch’s world: The last of the old media empires. New York: PublicAffairs.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frickel, S., & Gross, N. (2005). A general theory of scientific/intellectual movements. American Sociological Association, 70(2), 204–232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gabrenya, W. K., Kung, M., & Chen, L. (2006). Understanding the Taiwan indigenous psychology movement: a sociology of science approach. Journal of Cross-Cultural Psychology, 37(6), 597–622. doi:10.1177/0022022106290480.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibbs, J. P. (1990). Foundations of social theory (book). Social Forces, 69(2), 625–633.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstone, J. A. (1998). Initial conditions, general Laws, path dependence, and explanation in historical sociology. American Journal of Sociology, 104(3), 829–845.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gouldner, A. W. (1970). The coming crisis of western sociology. New York: Basic Books, Inc..

    Google Scholar 

  • Green, D. P., & Shapiro, I. (1994). Pathologies of rational choice theory: A critique of applications in political science. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gross, N., & Simmons, Solon (Eds.). (2014). Professors and their politics. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

  • Hechter, M. (1983). The Microfoundations of macrosociology. Philadelphia: Temple University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hechter, M., & Kanazawa, S. (1997). Sociological rational choice theory. Annual Review of Sociology, 23, 191–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckathorn, D. (2001). Sociological Rational Choice. In G. Ritzer & B. Smart (Eds.), Handbook of social theory (pp. 273–284). Thousand Oaks: SAGE.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Heidegren, C., & Lundberg, H. (2010). Towards a sociology of philosophy. Acta Sociologica, 53(1), 3–18. doi:10.1177/0001699309357831.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henley, M. M. (2015). Alternative and authoritative knowledge: the role of certification for defining expertise among doulas. Social Currents, 2(3), 260–279. doi:10.1177/2329496515589851.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henning, P. J. (2012). Behind the Crackdown on Insider Training. http://dealbook.nytimes.com/2012/03/01/behind-the-crackdown-on-insider-trading/?_r=0. Accessed 12 Nov 2016.

  • Hindman, D. B., & Wiegand, K. (2008). The big Three’s prime-time decline: a technological and social context. Journal of Broadcasting & Electronic Media, 52(1), 119–135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirsch, J. A. (2012). The little book of stock market cycles. Hoboken: John Wiley & Sons.

    Google Scholar 

  • Homans, G. (1958). Social behavior as exchange. American Journal of Sociology 63(6), 597–606.

  • Homans, G. (1964). Bringing Men Back In. American Sociological Review, 29(6), 809–818.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Homans, G. (1987). Certainties and doubts: Collected papers, 1962–1985. New Brunswick, New Jersey: Transaction, Inc..

    Google Scholar 

  • Horowitz, I. L. (1994). The decomposition of sociology. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huaco, G. A. (1986). Ideology and general theory: the case of sociological functionalism. Comparative Studies in Society and History, 28(1), 34–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huber, J. (1997). Rational choice models in sociology. The American Sociologist, 28(2), 42–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hughes, D. G. (1983). Computerized sales management. Harvard Business Review, 61(2), 102–112.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hughey, M. W. (1990). Internal contradictions of televangelism: ethical quandaries of that old time religion in a brave new world. International Journal of Politics, Culture, and Society, 4(1), 31–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hunt, S. (2000). ‘winning ways’: Globalisation and the impact of the health and wealth gospel. Journal of Contemporary Religion, 15(3), 331–347.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iannaccone, L. R. (1995a). Second thoughts: a response to Chaves, Demerath, and Ellison. Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion, 34(1), 113–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iannaccone, L. R. (1995b). Voodoo economics? Reviewing the rational choice approach to religion. Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion, 34(1), 76–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • International Sociological Association (2015). Research Committee on Rational Choice TheoryRC45: Past Boards.

  • Jacobs, J. A. (2013). In defense of disciplines: Interdisciplinarity and specialization in the research University. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jasso, G., & Rosenzweig, M. R. (1990). The new chosen people: Immigrants in the United States. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Joint Committee on Taxation, Congress of the United States (1981). General Explanation of the Economic Recovery Tax Act of 1981 (H. R. 4242, 97th Congress, Public Law 97–34). https://www.jct.gov/publications.html?func=startdown&id=2397. Accessed 17 July 2013.

  • Kalberg, S. (1994). Max Weber’s comparative-historical sociology. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kiesler, S., Siegel, J., & McGuire, T. W. (1984). Social psychological aspects of computer-mediated communication. American Psychologist, 39(10), 1123–1134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kilgore, S. B. (2016). The life and times of James S. Coleman. http://educationnext.org/life-times-james-s-coleman-school-policy-research. Accessed 1 Feb 2016.

  • Kiser, E., & Hechter, M. (1998). The debate on historical sociology: Rational choice theory and its critics. American Journal of Sociology, 104(3), 785–816.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuhn, T. S. (2012). The Structure of scientific revolutions. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ladd, A. E. (2014). Environmental disputes and opportunity-threat impacts surrounding natural gas fracking in Louisiana. Social Currents, 1(3), 293–311. doi:10.1177/2329496514540132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lichbach, M. I. (2003). Is rational choice theory all of social science? Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lopez, L. & La Roche, J. (2014). The CNBC Exec Who Developed ‘Mad Money’ Is Leaving to Reinvent An Iconic Wall Street TV Show. www.businessinsider.com/krakower-to-restart-wall-street-week-2014-5. Accessed 13 Nov 2016.

  • Macy, M. W., & Flache, A. (1995). Beyond rationality in models of choice. Annual Review of Sociology, 21, 73–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mallaby, A. (2016). The man who knew: The life and times of Alan Greenspan. New York: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marsden, P. V. (2005). The sociology of James S. Coleman. Annual Review of Sociology 31:1–24.

  • Marx, K. (1979). In M. Dobb (Ed.), A contribution to the critique of political economy. Chicago: Charles H. Kerr and Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mills, C. W. (1959). The sociological imagination. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moody, J., & Light, R. (2006). A view from above: The evolving sociological landscape. The American Sociologist, 37(2), 67–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mullins, N. C. (1973). Theories and theory groups in contemporary American sociology. New York: Harper & Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nickell, G. S., & Pinto, J. N. (1986). The computer attitude scale. Computers in Human Behavior, 2(4), 301–306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niskanen, W. A. (1988). Reaganomics: An Insider’s account of the policies and the people. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nobelprize.org. (2014). Gary S. Becker – Biographical. http://www.nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economic-sciences/laureates/1992/becker-bio.html. Accessed 1 Feb 2016.

  • Olegario, R. (1997). IBM and the two Thomas J. Watsons. In T. K. McCraw (Ed.), Creating modern capitalism: how entrepreneurs, companies, and countries triumphed in Three industrial revolutions (pp. 349–398). Boston: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1971). The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Osbourne, M. J., & Turner, M. A. (2010). Cost Benefit Analyses versus Referenda. Journal of Political Economy, 118(1), 156–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parsons, T. (1968). The Structure of social action, volume 1. A study in social theory with special reference to a group of recent European Writers. New York: The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pescosolido, B. A. (1992). Beyond rational choice: the social dynamics of how people seek help. American Journal of Sociology, 97(4), 1096–1138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powell, R. (1990). Nuclear deterrence theory: the search for credibility. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Prager, R. A. (1992). The effects of deregulating cable television: evidence from the financial markets. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 4(4), 347–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Proctor, W., & Phillips, S. (2012). The Templeton touch. West Conshohocken: Templeton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rawlings, C. M., McFarland, D. A., Dahlander, L., & Wang, D. (2015). Streams of thought: Knowledge flows and intellectual cohesion in a multidisciplinary era. Social Forces, 93(4), 1687–1722. doi:10.1093/sf/sov004.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reagan, R. (1981). Address to the nation on federal tax reduction legislation. July 27, 1981. www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=44120. Accessed 16 Sept 2014.

  • Reagan, R. (1986). Remarks to state chairpersons of the National White House Conference on small business. Presented at the old executive office building, August 15, Washington, D. C. http://www.reagan.utexas.edu/archives/speeches/1986/081586e.htm. Accessed 17 July 2013.

  • Riesman, D. (1963). The lonely crowd: a study of the changing American character. New Haven: Yale University Press.

  • Ritzer, G. (1975). Sociology: a multiple paradigm science. The American Sociologist, 10(3), 156–167.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roark, J. L., Johnson, M. P., Cohen, P. C., Stage, S., Lawson, A., & Hartmann, S. M. (2011). Understanding the American promise, volume 2: from 1865: a brief history of the United States. Boston: Bedford/St. Martin’s.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, M., & Murphy, D. (2009). Greed is good: maximization and elite deviance in America. Lanham: Rowman and Littlefield Publishers, Inc..

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodgers, D. T. (2011). Age of fracture. Cambridge: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott, J. (2000). Rational choice theory. In G. Browning, A. Halcli, & F. Webster (Eds.), Understanding Contemporary Society: theories of the Present (pp. 126–138). Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.

  • Sebba, L., & Berenblum, T. (2014). Victimology and the sociology of new disciplines: A research agenda. International Review of Victimology, 20(1), 7–30. doi:10.1177/0269758013511657.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shadnam, M. (2014). Heterologous and homologous perspectives on the relation between morality and organization: Illustration of implications for studying the rise of private military and security industry. Journal of Management Inquiry, 23(1), 22–37. doi:10.1177/1056492612472555.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Siler, K. (2012). Nascent institutional strategy in dynamic fields: The diffusion of science and technology studies. American Behavioral Scientist, 56(10), 1388–1412. doi:10.1177/0002764212454421.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slater, P. E. (1970). The pursuit of loneliness: American culture at the breaking point. Boston: Beacon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Slattery, M. (2003). Key ideas in sociology. Cheltenham: Nelson Thornes Ltd..

    Google Scholar 

  • Somers, M. R. (1998). ‘We’re no angels’: realism, rational choice, and relationality in social science. American Journal of Sociology, 104(3), 722–784.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sorokin, P. A. (1966). Sociological theories of today. New York: Harper & Row.

  • Stark, R., & Bainbridge, W. S. (1985). The future of religion: Secularization, revival, and cult formation. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Starke, R., & Finke, R. (2005). The churching of America, 1776–2005: winners and losers in our religious economy. New Brunswick: Rutgers University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stone, O. (1987). Wall Street. DVD. Los Angeles, CA: 20th Century Fox.

  • Swedberg, R. (1990). Economics and sociology: Redefining their boundaries: Conversations with economists and sociologists. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Swedberg, R. (1996). On analyzing the economy: The contribution of James S. Coleman. In J. Clark (Ed.), James S. Coleman (pp. 313–328). Bristol, PA: The Falmer Press.

  • Tax Foundation. (2013). Federal Individual Income tax Rates History: Nominal dollars, income years 1913-2013. http://taxfoundation.Org/sites/default/files/docs/fed_individual_rate_history_nominal.Pdf. Accessed 25 May 2015.

  • The Christian Broadcasting Network. (2014). About CBN. http://www.cbn.com/about/index.aspx?option=print. Accessed 12 Sept 2014.

  • Tierney, John. (2011). The left-leaning tower. The New York Times, July 22, pp. ED34. http://www.nytimes.com/2011/07/24/education/edl-24notebook-t.html?_r=0. Accessed 24 May 2015.

  • Tiryakian, E. A. (1979). The significance of schools in the development of sociology. In W. E. Sniezk, R. Fuhrman, & M. K. Miller (Eds.), Contemporary issues in theory and research: a Metasociological perspective (pp. 211–233). Westport: Greenwood Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turner, S. (2014). American sociology: From pre-disciplinary to post-normal. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Turner, J., & Turner, S. (1990). The impossible science: an institutional analysis of American sociology. Newbury Park: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • TV Basics. (2010). A Report on the Growth and Scope of Television. http://www.tvb.org/media/file/TV_Basics.pdf. Accessed 12 Sept 2014.

  • U. S. Department of Education. (1993). Digest of educational statistics. Washington, D.C.: U. S. Department of Education.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ulen, T. (2001). Information in the market economy—Cognitive errors and legal correctives. In S. Grundmann, W. Kerber, & S. Weatherill (Eds.), Party autonomy and the role of information in the internal market (pp. 98–130). Berlin: de Gruyter.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Neumann, J., & Morgenstern, O. (2004). Theory of games and economic behavior. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (1930) [1905]. The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. Translated by Talcott Parsons. New York: Routledge.

  • Williams, S. J. (2000). Is rational choice theory ‘unreasonable’? The neglected emotions. In M. S. Archer & J. Q. Tritter (Eds.), Rational choice theory: resisting colonisation. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wise, D. (1982). Wall Street’s financiers are bullish on micros. InfoWorld, July, 13–14.

  • Wood, C. V. (2012). Knowledge practices, institutional strategies, and external influences in the making of an interdisciplinary field: insights from the case of women’s and gender studies. American Behavioral Scientist, 56(10), 1301–1325. doi:10.1177/0002764212454427.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woolley, J. T., & Peters, G. (2014). The Achievements and Failures of the Reagan Presidency. www.presidency.ucsb.edu/reagan_100.php. Accessed 16 Sept 2014.

  • Young, C. (2009). The emergence of sociology from political economy in the United States: 1890 to 1940. Journal of the History of the Behavioral Sciences, 45(2), 91–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zafirovski, M. (2000). The rational choice generalization of neoclassical economics reconsidered: any theoretical legitimation for economic imperialism? Sociological Theory, 18(3), 448–471.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Harry Dahms, Lisa Keister, Larry Nichols, Richard Swedberg, and Steve Vaisey for their helpful feedback on previous versions of the manuscript.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Steven L. Foy.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and Permissions

About this article

Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Foy, S.L., Schleifer, C. & Tiryakian, E.A. The Rise of Rational Choice Theory as a Scientific/Intellectual Movement in Sociology. Am Soc 49, 16–36 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12108-017-9335-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12108-017-9335-3

Keywords

  • SIMs
  • Rational choice theory
  • Sociology of knowledge
  • Resources
  • Cultural context