Our modeling approach builds on existing affinity-based mixing compartment models (Hadeler 2012; Hadeler and Castillo-Chavez 1995; Busenberg and Castillo-Chavez 1991; Morin et al. 2014), where compartments represent different disease states. In most models, the probability of contact between individuals in different compartments depends only on their prevalence in the population (proportionate mixing). By contrast, we suppose that individuals mix preferentially, conditional on their own disease state and the (observable) disease states of others. As in (Fenichel et al. 2011), a mixing strategy depends on the relative costs of illness and illness avoidance.
The core of the model is an affinity framework for the preferential mixing structure. This framework has been shown to provide the most mathematically general solution to the problem of who mixes with whom (Blythe et al. 1991; Levin 1995). Groups may be defined by various shared attributes, including economic status, cultural or ethnic identity, geographical location, age, or disease awareness. In this paper, we define groups by their epidemiological status. The use of the affinity framework allows for three different factors to control the volume of contact between groups: (1) the size of each group, (2) the nominal activity levels of each group, and (3) the relative affinity/disaffinity between groups. We model the decision process behind changes in the affinity/disaffinity between groups, focusing on decisions made by susceptible or asymptomatically infectious (a subset of reactive) individuals. We hold the nominal level of activity (volume of contacts) constant throughout the course of the epidemic to measure more accurately the effect of changes in mixing preferences (see (Fenichel et al. 2011) for a treatment that affects only the volume of contacts for the reactive class and (Morin et al. 2014) for more details on varying contact volume versus contact type). To illustrate the approach, we first focus on a susceptible-infectious-recovered, SIR, model:
$$ \begin{array}{l}\frac{dS(t)}{dt}=-c\beta S(t){P}_{SI},\hfill \\ {}\frac{dI(t)}{dt}=c\beta S(t){P}_{SI}-\gamma I(t),\hfill \\ {}\frac{dR(t)}{dt}=\gamma I(t).\hfill \end{array} $$
(1)
As is standard with such a model, we let c be the nominal contact volume of all individuals. P
SI
is the conditional probability that a contact made by a susceptible individual, S(t), is with an infectious individual, I(t), and γ is the rate at which an individual recovers and becomes immune, R(t).
The affinity-based mitigation framework involves specification of a mixing matrix, P = (P
ij
), that is generally taken to satisfy three mixing axioms at each moment in time t (Busenberg and Castillo-Chavez 1991; Blythe et al. 1991; Castillo-Chavez et al. 1991):
-
1.
0 ≤ P
ij
≤ 1, for all i, j ∈ {S, I, R},
-
2.
\( {\displaystyle \sum_{j\in \left\{S,I,R\right\}}{P}_{ij}}=1 \), for all i ∈ {S, I, R},
-
3.
i(t)P
ij
= j(t)P
ji
, for all i, j ∈ {S, I, R}.
The first two axioms imply that P is a matrix of conditional probabilities, and the third implies that it is symmetric. Susceptible individuals carry the same expected risk of encountering infection as the expected risk of infectious individuals encountering susceptible individuals. It has been shown that the unique solution to these mixing axioms is given by
$$ {P}_{ij}=j(t)\left[\frac{M_i{M}_j}{V}+{\phi}_{ij}\right], $$
where
$$ \begin{array}{l}{M}_i=1-{\displaystyle \sum_{k\in \left\{S,I,R\right\}}k}(t){\phi}_{ik},\hfill \\ {}V={\displaystyle \sum_{\ell}\ell }(t){M}_{\ell },\hfill \end{array} $$
and Ф = (ϕ
ij
) is a symmetric affinity matrix, in this case 3 × 3.
The element ϕ
ij
may be interpreted as the effort that individuals in disease state i make to avoid individuals in disease state j (if ϕ
ij
< 0) or to associate with individuals in disease state j (if ϕ
ij
> 0). If all individuals in every disease state i make no effort to avoid individuals in disease state j ϕ
ij
= 0, we have classic proportionate mixing. The zero elements of the affinity matrix, Ф, reflect what we call avoidance-neutrality. That is, they show the individual to be neutral about a pairing event resulting from mixing behavior. By contrast, negative (positive) elements reflect the desire of an individual in one disease state to avoid (seek out) an individual in another disease state. This is a similar measure to that used in models of assortative mating (Karlin 1979) and selective mixing (Hyman and Li 1997) and is a form of a contact kernel (Gurarie and Ovaskainen 2013).
The elements of the affinity matrix describe what people want. What they actually get depends both on the preferences of others in the population and on their relative abundance. The mixing matrix P = (P
ij
) for the population thus derives from the affinity matrix and represents the conditional probabilities that an individual of disease state i contacts someone in disease state j. Reactive individuals, those with incentive to avoid infection, will maximize the net present value of disease avoidance taking into account the cost of illness and illness avoidance by choosing the effort to commit to preferential mixing the elements of Ф(t).
Formally, the decision problem for reactive individuals is to choose the level of mitigation effort, P(Φ(t)), to maximize the difference between the benefit of not being symptomatic, B, and the cost of mitigation effort, C(ϕ
SI
(t)), give the weight they place on future wellbeing (the discount factor ρ) and their planning horizon, T
$$ Ma{x}_{\phi_{SI}(t)}{\displaystyle \underset{t=0}{\overset{T}{\int }}{e}^{-\delta t}\left[B(t)\left(N(t)-I\left(P\left(\varPhi (t)\right),S(t)\right)\right)-C\left({\phi}_{SI}(t)\right)\right]dt} $$
(2)
Affinity-based mixing decisions can have four different effects on P:
-
Susceptible individuals seeking to reduce contact with infectious individuals can drive down the value of ϕ
SI
= ϕ
IS
directly;
-
Recovered individuals seeking to increase non-infection-causing contacts can drive up ϕ
SR
= ϕ
RS
and lower herd immunity thresholds;
-
Infectious individuals seeking to minimize contact with susceptible individuals can drive down SI, and possibly RI contacts, further reducing ϕ
SI
and reducing ϕ
IR
= ϕ
RI
,
-
In the limit, contact avoidance can induce an effective quarantine of infectious individuals (when P
SI
and P
RI
are very, very small, P
IS
and P
IR
are small, and P
II
is nearly 1).
In what follows, we assume that susceptible individuals are averse to mixing with symptomatic (infectious or otherwise) individuals. In the SIR case, omitting all other disease-risk aversion behaviors, Ф takes the form:
$$ \varPhi =\left(\begin{array}{ccc}\hfill 0\hfill & \hfill -a\hfill & \hfill 0\hfill \\ {}\hfill -a\hfill & \hfill 0\hfill & \hfill 0\hfill \\ {}\hfill 0\hfill & \hfill 0\hfill & \hfill 0\hfill \end{array}\right), $$
with 0 representing neutrality of mixing and −a < 0 representing the effort susceptible individuals make to avoid mixing with infectious individuals (Morin et al. 2014). This defines
$$ \begin{array}{c}\hfill {M}_S=1+ aI(t),\hfill \\ {}\hfill {M}_I=1+aS(t),\hfill \\ {}\hfill {M}_R=1,\hfill \\ {}\hfill V=1-S(t)\overline{\phi_S}-I(t)\overline{\phi_I}-R(t)\overline{\phi_R}=1+2aS(t)I(t),\hfill \end{array} $$
We may then write the mixing matrix of conditional probabilities as
$$ P=\left(\begin{array}{ccc}\hfill S(t)\frac{M_S^2}{V}\hfill & \hfill I(t)\left[\frac{M_S{M}_I}{V}-a\right]\hfill & \hfill R(t)\frac{M_S}{V}\hfill \\ {}\hfill S(t)\left[\frac{M_S{M}_I}{V}-a\right]\hfill & \hfill I(t)\frac{M_I^2}{V}\hfill & \hfill R(t)\frac{M_I}{V}\hfill \\ {}\hfill S(t)\frac{M_S}{V}\hfill & \hfill I(t)\frac{M_I}{V}\hfill & \hfill \frac{R(t)}{V}\hfill \end{array}\right). $$
To see whether action by susceptible individuals to avoid infected individuals can be strong enough in this structure to induce isolation of infectious individuals (private quarantine), we consider the conditions under which P
SI
= P
IS
= 0. More particularly, we construct a hard upper bound for the maximum effort that may be applied to avoidance subject to relative prevalence of the epidemiological classes. Supposing that neither population is zero, S(t) I(t) ≠ 0, we consider the case
which implies the convex quadratic
$$ S(t)I(t){a}^2+R(t)a-1=0, $$
with
$$ {a}^{\pm }=\frac{-R(t)\pm \sqrt{{\left(R(t)\right)}^2+4S(t)I(t)}}{2S(t)I(t)}. $$
Consider the positive and negative roots, a
+ and a−. For a greater than the positive root, \( a\in \left(\frac{-R(t)+\sqrt{{\left(R(t)\right)}^2+4S(t)I(t)}}{2S(t),I(t)},\infty \right) \), the mixing probability is less than zero, PSI < 0, and thus invalid. For \( a\in \left(\frac{-R(t)-\sqrt{{\left(R(t)\right)}^2+4S(t)I(t)}}{2S(t),I(t)},0\right) \) contacts between susceptible and infectious individuals would be desired, which violates our assumption that susceptible individuals are averse to mixing with infectious individuals. So, the effort by susceptible individuals to avoid infectious individuals is restricted to the range:
$$ a\in \left[0,\frac{-R(t)+\sqrt{{\left(R(t)\right)}^2+4S(t)I(t)}}{2S(t)I(t)}\right], $$
with proportionate mixing at the left end point, P
SI
(t) = I(t) the maximum probability of contact, and private quarantine of infectious individuals at the right end point, P
SI
(t) = 0, the minimum probability of contact. Economically, the occurrence of private quarantine implies that the expected marginal cost of illness dominates the marginal cost of illness avoidance.
The mixing strategy of the representative reactive individual generates infectious contact probabilities that lie anywhere between proportionate mixing and the privately driven quarantine of infectious individuals. Note that this may not be true for diseases like chicken pox or measles, where the costs of contracting the disease are much lower among children than adults. The parents of reactive children may actually seek out infection for their children to prevent the large cost of infection as an adult. In our case, however, reactive individuals assess the risk of illness and select the preferential mixing strategies that maximize the expected net benefits of those strategies where future and current costs of disease are the same. Specifically, individuals will increase effort to avoid infection up to the point where the marginal cost is offset by the marginal benefits (in terms of avoided illness) it yields. Efforts to avoid infection will be increasing in the cost of illness and decreasing in the cost of illness avoidance including any forgone benefits from contact with infectious individuals. In models without risk mitigation, disease dynamics may be completely characterized from initial conditions. With risk mitigation, the evolution of the epidemic reflects feedbacks between the cost of disease and disease avoidance on the one hand and averting behavior on the other (see (Fenichel and Horan 2007; Horan et al. 2011) for further discussion).