Have nations been maintaining their wealth for the past quarter century? Our results suggest that 95% of nations have enjoyed positive growth rates in IW during this period. However, if we change the measure from total to per capita, only 60% of nations under study present positive growth in IW. Notably, almost all European and North American countries have experienced increasing wealth in both absolute and per capita terms. In contrast, countries with negative growth in IW per capita are typically in Africa, Asia, or Latin America and the Caribbean (Fig. 1).
Figure 2 plots the average annual growth rate of wealth and natural capital per capita into four quadrants (Q1–Q4). Countries achieving both strong and weak forms of sustainability are few and far between (Q1). The concept of weak sustainability assumes that manufactured and natural capital are close substitutes. However, the concept of strong sustainability denies the assumption of this substitutability, at least for some critical elements of natural capital. Most countries, both developed and developing, fall into the group of running down natural capital and increasing other forms of capital (Q4). To our concern, there are still many countries that have degraded both natural capital and IW, particularly in Africa and Asia and the Pacific (Q3). It is highly likely that they are not successful in managing natural resources and transforming them into wealth. We briefly note that part of this rundown is traceable to international trade of natural resources, which is recorded as natural capital depletion of exporting countries. In contrast, Atkinson et al. (2012) in IWR 2012 account for virtual sustainability of resource importing nations by constructing consumption-based genuine savings.
If we take a closer look at the breakdown of the contributions of each capital asset, the composition varies even within high-IW-growth countries. For example, oil-rich gulf nations have converted massive natural capital into other types of capital, especially human capital. Other nations have been on a sustainable path primarily because they grow their produced capital, with very little rundown of their natural resources, or because they are poorly endowed with these resources in the first place.
We also include fishery resources as part of natural capital. Our calculation shows that around the world, the value of fishery stock has decreased from $2325 billion to $1713 billion. It is sobering to observe that among countries affiliated with a large amount of fishery stock, only Canada and Spain increased their level in the period from 1990 to 2014. However, the relative magnitude of fishery stock within natural capital is not large.
Has the world been preserving its wealth globally? Natural scientists have warned about global sustainability in terms of planetary boundaries (Steffen et al. 2015). Since the marginal utility of consumption is different across countries, aggregating national figures to reach global IW is not without problems.Footnote 3 That said, the most straightforward approach is simply to add up total change in capital assets in dollars. Produced and human capital per capita increased 94% and 28%, respectively, while natural capital per capita declined by 34% from 1992 to 2014, as shown in Fig. 3a.Footnote 4 Put together, wealth per capita has been slightly positive, especially over the last decade, as shown in Fig. 3b. In contrast, GDP per capita growth has been mostly linearly positive, except for an enormous drop in this trend in 2009 due to the Great Recession.
Only the comparison of wealth across time or space (nations), rather than the absolute value of wealth per se, can have welfare significance (Arrow et al. 2012). Acknowledging this, it is interesting to show wealth composition across the whole world. Figure 3c indicates that on average, human capital is responsible for more than half of IW. Natural capital has been substituted almost equally by produced and human capital.
However, if we turn back to cross-country data in Fig. 4, it seems to be human capital that substitutes natural capital, although cross sectional data can show only the relationship and not causality. A crude approximation suggests that if one starts from the state of natural capital being 100% of wealth, a 20% decrease in natural capital would translate into a 15% increase in human capital.
There are at least three exogenous factors that affect social well-being that we have not touched upon in the three capital channels: carbon damage, oil capital gains, and TFP. The three terms are added to the growth rate in IW per capita to arrive at IW per capita adjusted. As it turns out, carbon damage, calculated according to its effect on the economy of the nation that actually suffers the damages as a share of IW, affects small countries more because their IW tends not to be sufficiently large enough to absorb such exogenous shocks. Oil capital gains boost total wealth by an exogenous increase in the price of natural resources. Over the last quarter century, dozens of oil-exporting countries have experienced oil capital gains, while importing countries with negative oil capital gains comprise the majority (113 of 140 countries). Finally, the economy can also enjoy improved social well-being in the presence of an increase in TFP, representing technological progress, improvements in knowledge and institutions.Footnote 5 Put together, 58% of the studied countries have experienced an increase in IW per capita adjusted, including these three adjustments.
How does the IWI make a difference? It proves useful to compare our results with other indicators of economic development. GDP per capita is the most popular index to date for monitoring the progress of nations, but it has been criticized for sending an incorrect message regarding the sustainability of social well-being (Stiglitz et al. 2009). In actuality, Fig. 5 shows that while most countries have experienced growth in GDP per capita, many of them have experienced decreased IW per capita. Moreover, Quadrant 2 tends to include low- and lower-middle-income countries as well as resource-rich economies.
The Human Development Index (HDI) is a composite index of human capital (health and education) and income levels (GDP per capita). We find no apparent relationship between IWI and HDI (Figure S1a). For lower middle-income countries, their correlation is even slightly negative.
One of the indexes closest to ours is the World Bank’s genuine savings (GS), formally known as adjusted net savings, which also keeps track of savings in produced, human, and natural capital. The growth in IWI and GS are equivalent in theory but different in methodology. Among other differences, human capital is measured as outputs (i.e., return on education) in IWI instead of inputs (i.e., education expenditure) in GS. In terms of natural capital, the increase in agricultural land, discoveries in non-renewable natural capital, and capital gains are not recorded in GS because GS is more in line with national accounting (Lange et al. 2018). Thus, it was expected that IWI and GS do not correlate strongly, which turned out to be true (Figure S1c). In summary, the growth in IW does not resemble any of the plethora of other development indices with varied purposes, including GDP, HDI, happiness or even GS.
Finally, the publication of IWR 2018 almost coincided with the latest report on the Changing Wealth of Nations 2018 (CWN 2018) by the World Bank (Lange et al. 2018). As summarized in Table A.8 of the online supplement, it is safe to say that the two reports converge in terms of methodology. First, produced capital is recorded by a perpetual inventory method either by constructing data through investment and depreciation or by directly using other sources. Timber, non-timber forest benefits, and agricultural land compose renewable natural capital. However, notable differences remain, including the inclusion of urban land in produced capital (CWN), fishery resources in natural capital (IWR), protected land in natural capital (CWN), net foreign assets (CWN), and the three adjustment terms (IWR). Human capital accounting in CWN is based on household surveys, but the two reports have in common the basic mechanism of the net present value of earnings as a forward-looking shadow price. Overall, our capital composition of IW in 2014 works out to be 24%, 64%, and 11% for produced, human, and natural capital, respectively (Fig. 3c). This is almost in line with the result of CWN (27%, 64%, and 9%), where the inclusion of urban land and exclusion of fishery may explain the difference. A detailed investigation of how and why IWR and CWN differ in terms of empirical estimates should be performed in the future.
It is also important to place IW in an extended context of capital and income, which dates at least as far back as Fisher (1906). Ignoring capital gains, properly calculated national income is return on IW. As a rule of thumb, conventional wealth has been considered as several times the size of income, but this ratio has increased to 10–15 or even more in high-income countries due to an increase in financial assets (Piketty 2014). It is interesting to see the order of the magnitude when we expand the definition of wealth to include human and natural capital. Here, the wealth/income ratio is defined as IW divided by GDP, \( \beta = \frac{W}{Y} \), which works out to be 12.3 for the whole country sample in 2014. For robustness, we also check the wealth/income ratio in 2014 using World Bank’s total wealth (Lange et al. 2018) and adjusted net national income (constant 2010 US$, gross national income (GNI) minus consumption of fixed capital and natural resources depletion) as well as GNI (current US$) (World Bank 2019). On average, the wealth/ANNI ratio and the wealth/GNI ratio work out to be 21.0 and 15.8, respectively (see Figure SIII in the Supplementary Materials).
Given that Piketty’s definition of wealth comprises produced capital and financial assets in high-income countries and wealth here instead includes human and natural capital in all countries, these figures cannot be directly compared. However, we can safely state that human and natural capital are at least as important as financial assets. In addition, the rates of return on wealth are 4.8% for ANNI on total wealth of CWN, 6.3% for GNI on total wealth of CWN, and 8.1% for GDP on IW of IWR. However, even if they exceed the growth rates of income (ANNI, GNI and GDP), Piketty’s concern about inequality does not necessarily apply. To see this, recall that Piketty’s definition of capital comprises produced capital and financial assets, which he assumes mainly belong to capital owners, whereas human and natural capital income is largely attributed to a broader base of citizens in general. On the other hand, as pointed out by Barbier (2018), both human capital accumulation biased toward high-skill jobs and natural capital depreciation in low-income countries show some worrisome symptoms toward greater inequality in IW.