Abstract
An increase in the efficiency of natural gas fired residential appliances allows users to realize the same level of service, heating water for example, while using less natural gas. In addition to this technological benefit to the residential sector, the reduced demand for natural gas depresses the price of natural gas, resulting in pecuniary gains to other energy consumers and pecuniary losses to energy producers. The question we address in this study is whether purely pecuniary effects, those that follow from the price changes elicited by lower usage of natural gas, should enter the debate concerning the implementation of energy efficiency programs. To that end, we explore the price and social welfare impacts of natural gas energy efficiency standards by evaluating the impacts of a specific efficiency standard using the National Energy Modeling System. Our analysis indicates that purely pecuniary losses to producers are largely offset by pecuniary benefits to consumers. Our analysis also provides useful insight into the sources of these benefits and losses. Although our results are based on a specific model and efficiency standard, we believe that the results generalize to other efficiency programs and would be reproduced using other energy models.
Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
Standard deviation of USA heating degree days is 4.34 % of the mean and the elasticity of residential consumption is 0.9, so the standard deviation of consumption due to weather variation is approximately 4 % of its mean. Reduction for the water heater standard used for our analysis is 0.45 % of residential usage, almost an order of magnitude lower than weather induced variation. Source: EIA 1999, 2006.
More than one-quarter of all residential customers in New England pay a retail supplier other than the regulated utility for the generation of their electricity. Customers of both full-service utilities and restructured retail suppliers have experienced similar rate increases of just under 12 % so far this year (Source: http://www.eia.gov/todayinenergy/detail.cfm?id=17791).
This estimate is approximately equal to the change in consumer surplus where consumers are assumed to spend the entire savings from the price change on additional quantities of the same good. The change in consumer surplus can be calculated as \( \left({p}_0-{p}_s\right){q}_0+\frac{\left({p}_0-{p}_s\right)\left({q}_0-{q}_s\right)}{2} \). Our formulation omits only the last term which, for small changes in p and q is extremely small.
This is equivalent to a 75 percent government take − the average determined by Kepes et al. (2011) − where production costs are one third of revenue. . I.E. 3/4 of 2/3 of revenue is ½ of revenue.
Here, the term “reserves” is used as defined in the NEMS model rather than exactly complying with the SEC or other definitions.
Because the decrements are very small we apply multiples (4×, 6×, and 8×) of the decrements to three separate runs of NEMS and construct the results actually used as a linear interpolation between the results of those three runs and the reference run. Other, larger multiples were also run but not used because the estimated responses did not form a linear set with the lower multiples.
References
Berkhout, P. H. G., Muskens, J. C., & Velthuijsen, J. W. (2000). “Defining the Rebound Effect”. Energy Policy, 28, 425–432.
Borenstein, S., (2013). “a microeconomic framework for evaluating energy efficiency rebound and some implications”, Energy Institute at Haas (EI @ Haas) Working Paper Series, April 2013.
Borenstein, S., & Davis, L. W. (2012). The equity and efficiency of two-part tariffs in U.S. natural gas markets. Journal of Law and Economics, 55(1), 75–128.
Burtraw, D., Palmer, K., Paul, A., & Woerman, M. (2012). “Secular trends, environmental regulations, and electricity markets”. The Electricity Journal, 25(6), 35–47.
Croucher, M. (2012). Energy efficiency: is re-distribution worth the gains? Energy Policy, 45, 304–307.
DOE (2009). United States Department of Energy, “Residential heating products final rule technical support document”, available at http://www1.eere.energy.gov/buildings/appliance_standards/residential/heating_products_fr_tsd.html.
DOE (2010). “Natural gas revenue decoupling regulation: impacts on industry”, United States Department of Energy, July, 2010.
DOE (2013). “Report to congress on energy conservation standards activities”, United States Department of Energy, August 2013.
EIA (1999). Michael Morris, “The impact of temperature trends on short-term energy demand”, U.S. Energy Information Agency, September 1999.
EIA (2006). Costello, Dave, “Reduced form energy model elasticities from EIA’s Regional Short‐Term Energy Model (RSTEM)”, U.S. Energy Information Agency, May 9, 2006.
EIA (2012a). U.S. Energy Information Agency, “The electricity market module of the National Energy Modeling System Model Documentation, 2012”, December 2012.
EIA (2012b). U.S. Energy Information Agency, “Annual Energy Outlook 2013 Reference Case”, Table 8, DOE/EIA-0383(2012) , June 2012.
EIA (2013a). U.S. Energy Information Agency, “Sales of fossil fuels produced from Federal and Indian Lands, FY 2003 through FY 2012”, May 2013.
EIA (2013b). U.S. Energy Information Agency, “Annual Energy Outlook 2013 Reference Case Natural Gas Production by Category.”
EIA (2013c). U.S. Energy Information Agency, “Oil and gas supply module of the National Energy Modeling System: Model Documentation 2013”, May 2013.
EIA (2013d). U.S. Energy Information Agency, “Model Documentation Report: Natural Gas Transmission and Distribution Module of the National Energy Modeling”, January 2013.
EIA (2013e). U.S. Energy Information Agency, “Manufacturing Energy Consumption Survey (MECS), Cost of Natural Gas Used in Manufacturing Sector Has Fallen”, MECS 2010 — Release date: September 6, 2013.
EIA (2014). Table provided by EIA, August, 2014.
U.S. GAO (2007). United States Government Accountability Office, “Oil and gas royalties: a comparison of the share of revenue received from oil and gas production by the federal government and other resource owners”, GAO-07-676R.
Hausman, J. A., & Joskow, P. L. (1982). Evaluating the Costs and Benefits of Appliance Efficiency Standards. The American Economic Review, 72(2), Papers and Proceedings of the Ninety-Fourth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association (May, 1982), pp. 220–225.
Hotelling, H. (1931). “The economics of exhaustible resources”. Journal of Political Economy, 39(2), 137–175.
Kepes, J., B. Rodgers, P. Van Meurs, (2011). “Gas prices, other factors indicate changes in North American/shale play fiscal systems”, Oil and Gas Journal, Vol. 109, Issue 14, 4/04/2012.
Khazzoom, J. D. (1980). "Economic implications of mandated efficiency standards for household appliances". Energy Journal, 1(4), 21–40.
Kuuskraa, V. A., (2008). “Investment decision-making in the oil and gas supply sectors”, Advanced Resources International, January 21, 2008, EIA whitepaper downloaded from: http://www.eia.doe.gov/oiaf/emdworkshop/model_development.html.
Linn, J., L. Muehlenbachs, Y. Wang, (2014). “How do natural gas prices affect electricity consumers and the environment?”, Resources for the Future, July, 2014.
Naturalgas.org, (2013), “Industry and Market Structure”, http://www.naturalgas.org/business/industry.asp, accessed 4/3/2013 4:05 PM.
Pigou, A. C. (1924). The Economics of Welfare, 2nd edn, Macmillan
Sanstad, A. H., & Howarth, R. B. (1994). “Normal markets, market imperfections and energy efficiency”. Energy Policy, 22(10), 811–818.
Sanstad, A. H., Hanemann, W. M., & Auffhammer, M. (2006). End-use energy efficiency in a ‘post-carbon’ California economy: policy issues and research frontiers”. Berkeley, CA: California Climate Change Center at UC-Berkeley.
Sorrell, S., J. Dimitropoulos, (2008). “The rebound effect: microeconomic definitions, limitations and extensions”, Ecological Economics, (2008), 636–649.
Sutherland, R. (1991). “Market Barriers to Energy-Efficiency Investments”. The Energy Journal, 12(3), 15–34.
Sutherland, R. (1994). Energy efficiency or the efficient use of energy resources?”. Energy Sources, 16, 261–272.
Van Meurs, P., (2007). “Review of Conventional Oil and Gas Terms of Alberta”, July 29, 2007, downloaded from www.energy.gov.ab.ca/Org/pdfs/RifCONVENTIONAL_V14.pdf .
Vannan, M., W. Glass-Husain, (1999). “Managing Gas Assets through Simulation and Scenario Planning”, Presented at the International System Dynamics Conference, Wellington, New Zealand, 1999.
Varian, H. R. (1984). Microeconomic Analysis, Second Edition. New York: W.W. Norton & Company.
Watkins, G. C. (2001), “Atlantic Petroleum Royalties: Fair Deal or Raw Deal?”, June 2001, The AIMS [Atlantic Institute for Market Studies] Oil and Gas Papers (PAPER #2), Brian Lee Crowley, Series Editor.
Wiser, R., Bolinger, M., & Matt, S. C. (2005). “Easing the natural gas crisis: reducing natural gas prices through increased deployment of renewable energy and energy efficiency,” Environmental Energy Technologies Division, Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory. Berkeley, CA: University of California.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Carnall, M., Dale, L. & Lekov, A. The economic effect of efficiency programs on energy consumers and producers. Energy Efficiency 9, 647–662 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12053-015-9390-y
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12053-015-9390-y