Skip to main content
Log in

Analyzing the Publish-or-Perish Paradigm with Game Theory: The Prisoner’s Dilemma and a Possible Escape

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Science and Engineering Ethics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The publish-or-perish paradigm is a prevailing facet of science. We apply game theory to show that, under rather weak assumptions, this publication scenario takes the form of a prisoner’s dilemma, which constitutes a substantial obstacle to beneficial delayed publication of more complete results. One way of avoiding this obstacle while allowing researchers to establish priority of discoveries would be an updated “pli cacheté”, a sealed envelope concept from the 1700s. We describe institutional rules that could additionally favour high-quality work and publications and provide examples of such policies that are already in place. Our analysis should be extended to other publication scenarios and the role of other stakeholders such as scientific journals or sponsors.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Angell, M. (1986). Publish or perish: A proposal. Annals of Internal Medicine, 104, 261–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anonymous. (1938). Association of American Colleges Bulletin, 24.

  • Anonymous. (2000). Sur l’équation de Kolmogoroff, Pli cacheté déposé le 26 février 1940, ouvert le 18 mai 2000. CR Acad Sci Paris, S.I., 331:1031–1187.

  • Anonymous. (2010). Publish or perish. Nature, 467:252.

  • Bernhard, C. G. (1967). Award Ceremony Speech. The Nobel Prize in Physiology or Medicine: Ragnar Granit, Haldan K. Hartline, George Wald. Nobelprize.org. Nobel Media. http://www.nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/medicine/laureates/1967/press.html

  • Broad, W. J. (1981). The publishing game: Getting more for less. Science, 211, 1137–1139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cahn, R. W. (1989). Materials science—Aluminum-based glassy alloys. Nature, 341, 183–184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, A. (1983). A cache of 18th-century strings. The Galpin Society Journal, 36, 37–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coolidge, H. J., & Lord, R. H. (1932). Archibald Cary Coolidge: Life and letters (Vol. 308). Freeport: Books for Libraries Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • DFG. (2010). Information für die Wissenschaft Nr. 11 | 26. Februar 2010. Neuregelungen für Publikationsverzeichnisse in Anträgen, Antragsskizzen und Abschlussberichten. http://www.dfg.de/foerderung/info_wissenschaft/2010/info_wissenschaft_10_11/index.html

  • Erren, T. C. (2007). Judging words rather than journals or authors: A reminder that peer review continues after publication. QJM, 100, 799–800.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erren, T. C. (2009). On establishing priority of ideas: Revisiting the “pli cachete” (deposition of a sealed envelope). Medical Hypotheses, 72, 8–10.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erren, T. C., Shaw, D. M, & Gross, J. V. (2015). How to avoid haste and waste in occupational, environmental and public health research. Journal of Epidemiology and Community Health, 69(9), 823–825.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg, D., & Tirole, J. (1991). Game theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gad-el-Hak, M. (2004). Publish or perish—An ailing enterprise? Physics Today, 57, 61–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garfield, E. (1996). What is the primordial reference for the phrase ‘publish or perish’? Scientist, 10, 11.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hull, D., Pettifer, S. R., & Kell, D. B. (2008). Defrosting the digital library: Bibliographic tools for the next generation web. PLoS Computational Biology, 4, e1000204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ioannidis, J. P., & Khoury, M. J. (2014). Assessing value in biomedical research: The PQRST of appraisal and reward. JAMA, 312, 483–484.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ISI Web of Knowledge. (2015a). CitedReferenceSearch: Hartline HK. Citation Report: 48. h-index: 21.

  • ISI Web of Knowledge. (2015b). CitedReferenceSearch: Higgs PW. Citation Report: 22. h-index: 10.

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometria, 47, 263–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moseley, E. T., Hsu, D. J., Stone, D. J., et al. (2014). Beyond open big data: Addressing unreliable research. Journal of Medical Internet Research, 16, e259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neill, U. S. (2008). Publish or perish, but at what cost? The Journal of Clinical Investigation, 118, 2368.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • NIH. US National Institutes of Health. (2014). Changes to the Biosketch. http://nexus.od.nih.gov/all/2014/05/22/changes-to-the-biosketch/

  • Poundstone, W. (1993). Prisoner’s dilemma. Garden city: Anchor.

    Google Scholar 

  • Research Excellence Framework. (2014). Assessment framework and guidance on submissions. http://www.ref.ac.uk/pubs/2011-02/

  • Shaw, D. (2012). Unethical framework. In Times Higher Education, 26th Jan 2012.

  • Spence, M. (1973). Job market signaling. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87, 355–374.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Trimble, S. W. (2010). Reward quality not quantity. Nature, 467, 789.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Neumann, J. (1928). Zur Theorie der Gesellschaftsspiele. English edition (1959) (trans: Tucker, A. W., & Luce, R. D., Eds.), “On the theory of games of strategy”, contributions to the theory of games (vol. 4, pp. 13–42). Mathematische Annalen 100:295–320.

  • von Neumann, J. (1944). Theory of games and economic behavior. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, M. (2002). Rivals—Conflict as the fuel of science. London: Vintage, Random House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, L. (1942). The academic man: A study in the sociology of a profession. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors wish to thank Valérie Groß for comments and for supporting the literature search. Diligent reviewer comments are acknowledged. This manuscript was completed whilst TE was on sabbatical at the University of Oxford, Sleep and Circadian Neuroscience Institute (SCNi), and enjoyed stimulating working conditions at Brasenose College.

Author Contributions

Conceived the work: TCE. Designed the work: TCE PM. Wrote the appendix: PM. Wrote the manuscript: TCE PM DMS.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to T. C. Erren.

Appendix

Appendix

In “A Formal Application of Game Theory with Regard to Early or Late Publications: The Usual Publication Scenario and the Strong Publish-or-Perish Scenario”, we formally define a game theory basis of publishing early or late, define the usual publication scenario and introduce the strong publish-or-perish scenario. In “The Weak Publish-or-Perish Scenario in Terms of the Prisoners’ Dilemma”, we introduce the weak publish-or-perish scenario in terms of the prisoners’ dilemma; In “A Possible Option to Overcome the Publication Dilemma: Conditions Altered Appreciating Establishing Priority via the Pli Cacheté”, we introduce a possible option to overcome the dilemma by altering conditions to both appreciate quality and to establish priority.

A Formal Application of Game Theory with Regard to Early or Late Publications: The Usual Publication Scenario and the Strong Publish-or-Perish Scenario

For the sake of simplicity we restrict the discussion to only two competing researchers (or two competing research teams). In addition, we only consider two (pure) strategies: publishing early or publishing late. And we assume that the researchers are aware of the structure of the game as developed below and behave rationally, i.e., they strive for the largest payoffs. The basic structure of this publication scenario can be formally presented in terms of a symmetric two-players two-strategies no zero-sum game (Fudenberg and Tirole 1991).

Two researchers or research teams rival and work towards related discoveries. We assume that these scientists are at the same career stage, have attracted very similar amounts of grant money, and have comparable publication records. They can be interpreted as players in a game:

Player P1 :

the first researcher or research team (denoted Researcher A in the main text)

Player P2 :

the second researcher or research team (denoted Researcher B in the main text)

Both players have two options regarding how to act. Each player can arbitrarily choose one of both strategies.

Strategy s1 :

early but incomplete publication, with other important pieces of work being published later

Strategy s2 :

no early but only late publication after a full and convincing development of the issue

We assume that both strategies lead to a publication of an identical scientific content but s1 leads to two pieces of publication (two chapters) whereas s2 to only one piece. Given s1 we assume additionally that the first chapter is suffering from minor errors and/or some confusing terminology and that these issues are successfully settled with publication of the second chapter. Given s2 we assume that the work published in one piece is consolidated and free of errors. In the following we use “early publication” or “late publication” as short narratives when we refer to s1 or s2, respectively.

Both players will receive an academic reward as payoff (utility) depending on the strategies that are chosen.

Utility uijk :

payoff (a real number) that player Pk would receive if player P1 chose strategy si and player P2 chose strategy sj, 1 ≤ i, j, k ≤ 2.

The game can be summarized as a bi-matrix (Table 3).

Table 3 Bi-matrix summarizing the formalized game of two players Pk, 1 ≤ k ≤ 2, who may play different combinations of two strategies, s1 and s2, to receive awards uijk, 1 ≤ i, j, k ≤ 2

Two intra-cell conditions and one inter-cell condition seem to be obvious in order to match the usual publication scenario (we note that these conditions do not hold in “A Possible Option to Overcome the Publication Dilemma: Conditions Altered Appreciating Establishing Priority via the Pli Cacheté”, pli cacheté):

1):

If P1 and P2 published simultaneously and early, both would receive the same award: u111 = u112 = a.

2):

If P1 and P2 published simultaneously and late, both would receive the same award: u221 = u222 = d.

3):

The scenario is assumed to be symmetric: u121 = u212 = b, u122 = u211 = c.

The usual publication scenario is presented in Table 4.

Table 4 Bi-matrix summarizing the formalized game of two researchers P1 and P2, who may choose different combinations of two publication strategies, s1 and s2, to receive awards a, b, c, or d

If early publication is favorable one additional intra-cell condition will hold:

4):

If P1 published early but P2 late, P1 would receive a higher payoff than P2: u121 = b > u122 = c.

Because the scenario is symmetric we also have: u212 = b > u211 = c. We believe that the additional assumption 4) is almost evident because we assumed that the strategies s1 and s2 do not lead to different scientific contents published.

The following six inter-cell conditions are assumed additionally to match a strong publish-or-perish scenario:

5):

If P1 and P2 both published early, each would receive less than P1 given that P1 published early but P2 late: b > a.

6):

If P1 and P2 published early, each would receive more than P2 given that P1 published early but P2 late: a > c.

7):

If P1 and P2 both published late, each would receive less than P1 given that P1 published early but P2 late: b > d.

8):

If P1 and P2 both published late, each would receive more than P2 given that P1 published early but P2 late: d > c.

9):

If P1 and P2 both published late, each would receive less than P1 and P2 given that P1 published early: a > d.

10):

If P1 and P2 both published late, both would receive in sum less than P1 and P2 given that P1 published early but P2 published late: b + c > d + d.

Given conditions 5)–10) we have b > a > d > c and b + c > 2d.

Given the strict publish-or-perish scenario we have one and only one Nash equilibrium in pure strategies: (s1, s1) with utilities (a, a). A Nash equilibrium is an outcome from which each player could only do worse by unilaterally changing the strategy. Illustrative examples of Nash equilibria are presented in Chapter 1.2; the existence and properties of such equilibria are discussed by applying powerful mathematics in Chapter 1.3 of the textbook by Fudenberg and Tirole (1991). We conclude that, given this strong scenario and that both players behave rationally, each researcher will publish as early as he/she can.

The Weak Publish-or-Perish Scenario in Terms of the Prisoners’ Dilemma

A Formal Application of Game Theory with Regard to Early or Late Publications: The Usual Publication Scenario and the Strong Publish-or-Perish Scenario” introduced the strong publish-or-perish scenario. We believe that conditions 1)–8) are evident because we assumed that the strategies s1 and s2 do not lead to different scientific contents published. Next, we will relax the other two conditions to analyse whether this has impact on the decisions of the researchers and define the weak publish-or-perish scenario:

1) through 8):

These conditions remain unchanged.

9*):

If P1 and P2 both published late, each would receive more than P1 and P2 given that P1 and P2 published early: d > a. (changed)

10*):

If P1 and P2 both published late, both would receive in sum more than P1 and P2 given that P1 published early but P2 published late: d + d ≥ b + c. (changed)

Because conditions 9) and 10) are changed into 9*) and 10*) a higher value is given to a late publication. This is a rather strong modification because both conditions were changed into strict inequalities of opposite direction. The order of utilites is now b > d > a > c, and we have 2d > b + c. We note that the game has now been specified to a “prisoners’ dilemma” (Fudenberg and Tirole 1991). To see why we have to identify strategy s1 with betraying (“defecting = confessing”) and s2 with cooperating (“remaining silent = denying”).

The prisoner’s dilemma is an example of a game that shows why two individuals might not cooperate, even if it appears that it is in their best interests to do so. For further discussions see, e.g., http://www.prisoners-dilemma.com.

Thus, as rational players the scientists will publish as early as possible although our modification of the awards was clearly in favor of a late publication. In this analysis we maximized the absolute payoffs as it is usual in game theory (Fudenberg and Tirole 1991). Note that our conclusion is also true if we change the metric to measure the difference in awards between players: both assure to have no deficit in comparison to the competitor’s award if they publish early [strategy of minimizing the maximum possible loss relative to the competitor (Kahneman and Tversky 1979)]. Publishing early is the dominant strategy for both researchers.

In conclusion, simultaneous early publication is the only Nash equilibrium in the game: (s1, s1) with utilities (a, a). The dilemma then is that simultaneous late publication yields a better outcome than simultaneous early publication, but if the researchers behave rationally both will publish early although they know that this is not optimal. And this is so although we modified conditions 9) and 10) into 9*) and 10*) to reflect the higher value of a later and more developed publication. This weak publish-or-perish scenario is shown to be a publication dilemma equivalent to the prisoners’ dilemma.

A Possible Option to Overcome the Publication Dilemma: Conditions Altered Appreciating Establishing Priority via the Pli Cacheté

Obviously, we have to change the conditions more substantially to affect the rational strategy of both players. To do so we go back to Table 3 and introduce conditions to reflect pli cacheté (Erren 2009). The ‘‘pli cacheté” (deposition of a sealed envelope) approach could allow to establish priority of thinking and doing a posteriori, i.e., when the envelope is opened.

We assume that both players P1 and P2 used a pli cacheté and, without loss of generality, that the sealed information revealed that P2 had priority. Alternatively, we may have assumed that only P2 used the pli cacheté and that P2 had in fact priority according to the sealed information. We note that this version does not change the structure of the game. The third situation (only P2 used pli cacheté but P1 was proven to be first) means that pli cacheté had no effect on the outcome and we are back in a situation without pli cacheté as discussed before. Thus, it suffices to analyse the case that both players P1 and P2 used a pli cacheté and that the sealed information revealed that P2 had priority.

In addition, we assume that P2 did not know a priori whether P2 had priority or not but P2 believed/hoped so. Of course, we make the same assumption about P1. Finally, we assume that the sealed letters will be opened in all four situations described by Table 3.

This situation is assumed to be known to the scientific community so that late publications are appreciated by Journals, Universities and other stake holders. Thus, we assume that pli cacheté is well established as a procedure within the scientific community. To exemplify, let us suppose P1 published results in a leading journal. P2, using the pli cacheté, claims to have obtained (a) identical or (b) extended results earlier. In case (a), the journal should publish a short communication authored by P2. The journal should also publish a note clearly stating that P2 was first. In case (b), the journal should publish the whole research of P2. This will allow recognition of P2 having been “first” within the scientific community.

The following four intra-cell conditions are used to describe the pli cacheté publication scenario:

1pc):

If P1 and P2 published simultaneously and early, P2 would receive a higher payoff than P1: u111 < u112.

2pc):

If P1 published early but P2 late, P2 would receive a higher payoff than P1: u121 < u122.

3pc):

If P1 published late but P2 early, P2 would receive a higher payoff than P1: =u211 < u212 (P2 was definitely the first)

4pc):

If P1 and P2 published simultaneously and late, P2 would receive a higher payoff than P1: u221 < u222.

Furthermore, the following four inter-cell conditions are set to match the pli cacheté publication scenario (note that publishing in one piece is appreciated):

5pc):

If P1 and P2 both published early, P1 would receive the same but P2 less given that P1 published early but P2 late: u111 = u121, u112 < u122.

6pc):

If P1 and P2 published early P1 would receive less but P2 the same given that P1 published later but P2 early: u111 < u211, u112 = u212.

7pc):

If P1 and P2 both published late, P1 would receive more but P2 the same given that P1 published early but P2 late: u121 < u221, u122 = u222.

8pc):

If P1 and P2 both published late, each would receive more than P2 given that P1 published early but P2 late: u211 = u221, u212 < u222.

It follows that

A):

If P1 and P2 both published early, each would receive less than given that P1 and P2 published late: u111 < u221 (because u111 = u121 < u221), u112 < u222 (because u112 < u122 = u222),

B):

If P1 and P2 both published late, both would receive in sum more than under all other scenarios: u111 + u112 < u221 + u222, u121 + u122 < u221 + u222,. and u211 + u212 < u221 + u222.

Obviously, P1 is striving under all conditions to reach the maximum utility u211 = u221 (because u111 < u211 and u121 < u221), whereas P2 is trying to receive u122 = u222 (because u112 < u122 and u212 < u222). Thus, both players will choose the strategy “late publication” to maximise the individual pay-off. We have one and only one Nash equilibrium in pure strategies (s2, s2) with utilities (u221, u222). This equilibrium leads to the maximum outcome for the group because of statement B).

Our main conclusion is that this rather simple and first-step analysis revealed pli cacheté as a possible option to achieve more high-quality publications.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Erren, T.C., Shaw, D.M. & Morfeld, P. Analyzing the Publish-or-Perish Paradigm with Game Theory: The Prisoner’s Dilemma and a Possible Escape. Sci Eng Ethics 22, 1431–1446 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11948-015-9701-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11948-015-9701-x

Keywords

Navigation