Skip to main content
Log in

Transparent pricing: theory, tests, and implications for marketing practice

  • Original Empirical Research
  • Published:
Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In today’s retail markets, products display opaque pricing, i.e., a single number that provides no information about the allocation of the retail proceeds among agents who bring the product to market. We study transparent pricing, which is an alternative strategy in which allocation information is revealed. We differentiate transparent pricing from related marketing practices such as social marketing, cause-related marketing, and pay-what-you-want. Using controlled experiments in multiple product categories with diverse sampling frames, we find that transparent prices systematically alter consumer utility functions and stated choice behavior. Our results support explanations drawn from both neoclassical and behavioral economic theory, including inequity aversion, procedural justice, and altruism. Classical theory predicts that price transparency should have little effect on consumer behavior. However, results from behavioral economics suggest that consumers may relax “self-interest” in the face of transparent prices, leading to counter-intuitive preferences. For example, in one set of studies we observe a significant proportion of consumers selecting the more expensive of two replicates of the same product. In another study, a subset of motorists willingly pays higher gasoline taxes for the same gallon of gas, increasing the overall price per gallon. We explain this behavior via parameterized utility functions that contain both self-interested and other-interested components moderated by characteristics of the decision-maker and characteristics of the choice context.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1
Figure 2
Figure 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Exceptions include backward sloping demand curves when consumers impute quality from price. However, as will be evident, this phenomenon does not apply in the cases studied here.

  2. A longer version of the paper containing results for standard economic hypotheses is available on request.

  3. We assessed the reasonableness of this assumption in a companion research project. Results hold independently of which agent is selected as the focal agent.

  4. We experimentally manipulate the share of price going to the focal agent so that A*(⋅) designates a specific fixed allocation to A* in a given experimental condition. For example, in experiments involving music CDs, the low level going to A* (the artist) is 8%. The notation indicates that one can replace the variable argument (⋅) with a constant (Lo); i.e., A*(Lo)≡8% and that this level is determined exogenously across subjects.

  5. These arguments are presented in a note available from the authors.

  6. Not unexpectedly, students believe higher shares should go to taxes than do adults. The student’s cumulative distribution lies significantly to the right of that for adults.

References

  • Bergh, A. (2008). A critical note on the theory of inequity aversion. Journal of Socio-Economics, 37(5), 1789–1796.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, G. E., & Ockenfels, A. (2000). ERC: a theory of equity, reciprocity, and cooperation. American Economic Review, 90(1), 166–193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, L. E., Warlop, L., & Alba, J. W. (2003). Consumer perceptions of price (un)fairness. Journal of Consumer Research, 29(4), 474–491.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bordonaro, G. (2009). Progressive’s ‘name your price’ tool aims for cost transparency. Hartford Business Journal, 6/29/09.

  • Boyd, E. D., & Bhat, S. (1998). The role of dual Entitlement and equity theories in consumers' formation of fair price judgments: an investigation within a business-to-business service setting. Journal of Professional Services Marketing, 17(1), 1–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C. F. (2003). Behavioral game theory. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C. F., & Fehr, E. (2006). When does ‘Economic Man’ dominate social behavior? Science, 311(5757), 47–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C. F., & Thaler, R. H. (1995). Anomalies: ultimatums, dictators and manners. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(2), 209–219.

    Google Scholar 

  • Charness, G., & Rabin, M. (2002). Understanding social preferences with simple tests. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(3), 817–869.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, W., & Knopper, S. (2004). Wal-Mart battles labels over CD prices. Rolling Stone Magazine, 28, 26–30. October.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cui, D., & Curry, D. J. (2005). Prediction in marketing using the support vector machine. Marketing Science, 24(4), 595–615.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 817–868.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gendall, P., Holdershaw, J., & Garland, R. (1997). The effect of odd pricing on demand. European Journal of Marketing, 31(11/12), 799–813.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilbride, T. J., & Allenby, G. M. (2004). A choice model with conjunctive, disjunctive, and compensatory screening rules. Marketing Science, 23(3), 391–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hahn, G. J., & Shapiro, S. S. (1966). A catalog and computer program for the design and analysis of orthogonal symmetric and asymmetric fractional factorial experiments. Schenectady: General Electric Technical Information Series.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, R. W. (2006). When the means justify the ends: effects of observability on the procedural fairness and distributive fairness of resource allocations. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 19(4), 303–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hensher, D. A., & Johnson, L. W. (1981). Applied discrete-choice modeling. New York: Croom Helm London, John Wiley & Sons.

    Google Scholar 

  • Homans, G. C. (1961). Social behaviour: Its elementary forms. New York: Harcourt Brace.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., & Thaler, R. H. (1986). Fairness and the assumptions of economics. Journal of Business, 59(4), 285–300.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim, J., Natter, M., & Spann, M. (2009). Pay what you want: a new participative pricing mechanism. Journal of Marketing, 73(1), 44–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lofton, L. (2008). Culture of cost transparency a goal of new MSMA president. The Mississippi Business Journal, 8/4/08.

  • Louviere, J. J., Hensher, D. A., & Swait, J. D. (2000). Stated choice methods. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Luo, Y. (2007). The independent and interactive roles of procedural, distributive, and interactional justice in strategic alliances. Academy of Management Journal, 50(3), 644–664.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maxwell, S. (1995). What makes a price increase seem “fair”? Pricing Strategy and Practice, 3(4), 21–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maxwell, S. (2002). Rule-based price fairness and its effect on willingness to purchase. Journal of Economic Psychology, 23(2), 191–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paolilli, A. L. (2009). About the “economic” origin of altruism. Journal of Socio-Economics, 38(1), 60–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rossi, P. E., Allenby, G. M., & McCulloch, R. (2005). Bayesian statistics and marketing. New York: Wiley.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rotemberg, J. J. (2008). Minimally acceptable altruism and the ultimatum game. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 66(3–4), 457–476.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scarpa, R., Thiene, M., & Train, K. (2007). Utility in WTP space: A tool to address confounding random scale effects in destination choice to the Alps. Working paper in Economics 15/06. Hamilton: University of Waikato.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sinha, I. (2000). Cost transparency: the net’s real threat to prices and brands. Harvard Business Review, March–April, 43–50.

  • Thibaut, J., & Walker, L. (1975). Procedural justice: A psychological analysis. Hillsdale: Erlbaum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Train, K. (2009). Discrete choice methods with simulation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tyran, J. R., & Sausgruber, R. (2006). A little fairness may induce a lot of redistribution in democracy. European Economic Review, 50(2), 469–485.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vaidyanathan, R., & Aggarwal, P. (2003). Who is the fairest of them all? An attributional approach to price fairness perceptions. Journal of Business Research, 56(6), 453–463.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xia, L., Monroe, K. B., & Cox, J. L. (2004). The price is unfair! A conceptual framework of price fairness perceptions. Journal of Marketing, 68(4), 1–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgement

Professor Curry thanks John Dinsmore, Grace Guo, Xiaoqi Han, Helene Deval, Doug Ewing, and Scott Wright – students in his PhD Seminar on Discrete-Choice Modeling – for insights drawn from hierarchical Bayesian analyses about the gasoline data from the Adult sample. This research was partially funded by a grant from the College of Business, University of Louisville.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Robert E. Carter.

Appendices

Appendix A

Table 5 Example choice set for music CDs

Appendix B

Table 6 Allocations to each of the supply side agents by category

Appendix C

Table 7 Perceptions of “should” allocations to agents

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Carter, R.E., Curry, D.J. Transparent pricing: theory, tests, and implications for marketing practice. J. of the Acad. Mark. Sci. 38, 759–774 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11747-010-0189-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11747-010-0189-2

Keywords

Navigation