Skip to main content
Log in

An integral representation of elasticity and sensitivity for stochastic volatility models

  • Published:
Mathematics and Financial Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper presents a generic probabilistic approach to study elasticities and sensitivities of financial quantities under stochastic volatility models. We describe the shock elasticity, the quantile sensitivity and the vega value of cash flows with respect to perturbation of the volatility function of the model. The main contribution is to establish explicit formulae for these elasticities and sensitivities based on a novel application of the exponential measure change technique in Palmowski and Rolski (Bernoulli 8(6):767–785 2002). We carry out explicit calculations for the Heston model and the 3/2 stochastic volatility model, and derive explicit expressions in terms of model parameters.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Sect. 3.1 for the single volatility factor case, and see Appendix A for a discussion on the possible extension to the case of multivariate volatility factors.

  2. Hansen and Scheinkman [12] start with a perturbed reference growth process \(S_t^{\epsilon }\) being a martingale, then in their setting, we have \( \rho _t=-\frac{1}{t} \frac{\partial }{\partial \epsilon }\Big |_{\epsilon =0} \log \mathbb {E}\left[ S_t^{\epsilon } D_t\right] \), and refer to the first equation on page 2 of Hansen and Scheinkman [12] for this definition of the shock elasticity (or the price of growth-rate risk).

  3. In the proof of part (c) of Theorem 1 in Cheridito et al. [6], even though the proof of it needs to use results of part (a) and part (b), the results of part (a) and part (b) are only used to show that the SDE (57) in Cheridito et al. [6] has a unique solution. Because of this, for the proof that \(E^P[Z_T]=1\) where Z is constructed from possibly non-affine processes \(V_t\), one can just repeat the proof of Theorem 1 of Cheridito et al. [6] verbatim. This is in the spirit of the discussion after Proposition 2.1 in Hurd and Kuznetsov [14].

References

  1. Alexander, C., Sarabia, J.M.: Quantile uncertainty and value-at-risk model risk. Risk Anal. 32(8), 1293–1308 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Bernard, C., Cui, Z., McLeish, D.: On the martingale property in stochastic volatility models based on time-homogeneous diffusions. Math. Finance 27(1), 194–223 (2017)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  3. Borodin, A., Salminen, P.: Handbook of Brownian Motion, 2nd edn. Birkhäuser, Basel (2002)

    Book  MATH  Google Scholar 

  4. Borovička, J., Hansen, L.P., Scheinkman, J.A.: Shock elasticities and impulse responses. Math. Financ. Econ. 8(4), 333–354 (2014)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  5. Carr, P., Sun, J.: A new approach for option pricing under stochastic volatility. Rev. Deriv. Res. 10, 87–150 (2007)

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  6. Cheridito, P., Filipović, D., Kimmel, R.: Market price of risk specifications for affine models: theory and evidence. J. Financ. Econ. 83, 123–170 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Cui, Z., Nguyen, D.: Density of generalized Verhulst process and Bessel process with constant drift. Lith. Math. J. 56(4), 463–473 (2016)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  8. Fournié, E., Lasry, J.-M., Lebuchoux, J., Lions, P.-L., Touzi, N.: Applications of Malliavin calculus to Monte Carlo methods in finance. Finance Stoch. 3(4), 391–412 (1999)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  9. Glasserman, P.: Monte Carlo Methods in Financial Engineering, vol. 53. Springer, Berlin (2003)

    Book  MATH  Google Scholar 

  10. Hansen, L.: Modeling the long run: valuation in dynamic stochastic economies. In: Fisher–Schultz Lecture at the European Meetings of the Econometric Society (2008)

  11. Hansen, L.P., Scheinkman, J.A.: Long-term risk: an operator approach. Econometrica 77(1), 177–234 (2009)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  12. Hansen, L.P., Scheinkman, J.A.: Pricing growth-rate risk. Finance Stoch. 16(1), 1–15 (2012)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  13. Hong, L.J., Hu, Z., Liu, G.: Monte Carlo methods for value-at-risk and conditional value-at-risk: a review. ACM Trans. Model. Comput. Simul. (TOMACS) 24(4), 1–37 (2014)

    MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  14. Hurd, T., Kuznetsov, A.: Explicit formulas for Laplace transforms of stochastic integrals. Markov Process Relat. Fields 14, 277–290 (2008)

    MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  15. Linetsky, V.: The spectral representation of Bessel processes with constant drift: applications in queueing and finance. J. Appl. Probab. 41, 327–344 (2004)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  16. Palmowski, Z., Rolski, T.: A technique for exponential change of measure for Markov processes. Bernoulli 8(6), 767–785 (2002)

    MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  17. Pham, H.: A large deviations approach to optimal long term investment. Finance Stoch. 7(2), 169–195 (2003)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  18. Ruf, J.: The martingale property in the context of stochastic differential equations. Electron. Commun. Probab. 20(34), 1–10 (2015)

    MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  19. Sin, C.: Complications with stochastic volatility models. Adv. Appl. Probab. 30(1), 256–268 (1998)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  20. Yu, J.: On leverage in a stochastic volatility model. J. Econom. 127(2), 165–178 (2005)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank the anonymous referee for stimulating remarks, and comments which significantly help improve the paper. The usual disclaimer applies. The research of Duy Nguyen is partially supported by a Marist College summer research grant.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Zhenyu Cui.

Ethics declarations

Conflicts of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Human/Animals participants

This research does not involve human participants or animals.

A Discussion of the case of multivariate volatility factors

A Discussion of the case of multivariate volatility factors

In this section, we shall illustrate that similar representations like Eq. (5) also hold for the case of multivariate stochastic volatility factors, which is consistent with the model considered in Hansen and Scheinkman [12]. In the following, we shall illustrate the details of this extension. Assume that the underlying state vector process V is n-dimensional, where each entry of V satisfies the following SDE

$$\begin{aligned} dV^{(i)}_t&=\mu (V^{(i)}_t)dt+\sigma (V^{(i)}_t) dZ_t^{(i)}, \quad V_0^i=v_0^i, \quad i=1,\ldots ,n. \end{aligned}$$

Consider the following stochastic volatility model

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{ dS}_t}{S_t}=r\, dt+ \sum _{i=1}^{n} m_i(V^{(i)}_t)\,{ dW}_t^{(i)}, \quad i=1,\ldots ,n, \end{aligned}$$
(25)

and this can be thought of as the multivariate generalization of the model in Eq. (2).

In line with Hansen and Scheinkman [12], we assume that \(Z_t:=(Z_t^{(1)}, \ldots , Z_t^{(n)})\) is an n-dimensional Brownian motion, which means that the individual entries \(Z_t^{(i)}\) are independent of each other. Similarly we assume that \(W_t:=(W_t^{(1)}, \ldots , W_t^{(n)})\) is an n-dimensional Brownian motion. Then we assume that there is a constant correlation between \(W_t^{(i)}\) and \(Z_t^{(j)}\), i.e. \(\mathbb {E}[{ dW}_t^{(i)} dZ_t^{(j)}]=\rho _i\delta _{ij} \,dt, i=1,\ldots , n\), where \(\delta _{ij}\) is the Kronecker Delta notation. Note that \(W_t^{(i)}\) and \(Z_t^{(j)}\) are independent of each other for \(i\ne j\). From the Cholesky decomposition, we can write

$$\begin{aligned} { dW}_t^{(i)}=\rho _i \,dZ_t^{(i)}+\sqrt{1-\rho _i^2}\,d\bar{Z}_t^{(i)} \end{aligned}$$

with \(\mathbb {E}[dZ_t^{(i)}d\bar{Z}_t^{(i)}]=0\) for some standard Brownian motion \(\bar{Z}_t^{(i)}\) independent of \(Z_t^{(i)}\). Note that we also have that \(\bar{Z}_t^{(i)}\) are independent of each other for \(i=1,\ldots , n\), i.e. the vector \(\bar{Z}_t:=(\bar{Z}_t^{(1)}, \ldots , \bar{Z}_t^{(n)})\) is also an n-dimensional Brownian motion independent of \(Z_t\). Define two auxiliary functions \(g_i(\cdot )\) and \(h_i(\cdot )\) for \(i=1,2,\ldots ,n\) as in Eq. (3), then from Itô’s lemma, we have

$$\begin{aligned} dg_i(V^{(i)}_t)=h_i(V^{(i)}_t) dt+ m_i(V^{(i)}_t) dZ_t^{(i)}. \end{aligned}$$

Integrating both sides from 0 to T, it follows that

$$\begin{aligned} g_i(V^{(i)}_T)-g_i(V^{(i)}_0)&=\int _0^T h_i(V^{(i)}_s) ds +\int _0^T m_i(V^{(i)}_s) \,dZ_s^{(i)}. \end{aligned}$$
(26)

From Eqs. (25) and (26), and the fact that \(\bar{Z}_t^{(i)}\) are independent of each other for \(i=1,\ldots , n\), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} S_T&=S_0 \exp \left( rT-\frac{1}{2} \int _0^T \sum _{i=1}^{n} m_i^2(V^{(i)}_s) ds + \int _0^T \sum _{i=1}^{n} \rho _i m_i(V^{(i)}_s) dZ_s^{(i)}\right. \\&\quad \quad \left. +\int _0^T \sum _{i=1}^{n} \sqrt{1-\rho _i^2} m_i(V^{(i)}_s) d\bar{Z}_s^{(i)}\right) \\&=S_0 \exp \left( rT-\frac{1}{2} \int _0^T \sum _{i=1}^{n} m_i^2(V^{(i)}_s) ds + \sum _{i=1}^{n} \rho _i \Big (g_i(V^{(i)}_T)-g_i(V^{(i)}_0)-\int _0^T h_i(V^{(i)}_s) ds\Big ) \right. \\&\quad \quad \left. + \sum _{i=1}^{n} \sqrt{1-\rho _i^2} \int _0^T m_i(V^{(i)}_s) d\bar{Z}_s^{(i)}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

Since \(\bar{Z}^{(i)}\) is independent of \(Z^{(i)}\) and since \(\bar{Z}^{(i)}\) (and \(Z^{(i)}\)) are independent of each other, we have that conditioning on the functionals of the vector stochastic processes

$$\begin{aligned} \left( V_T^{(1)},\ldots ,V_T^{(n)}, \int _0^T m_1^2(V^{(1)}_s) ds,\ldots ,\int _0^T m_n^2(V^{(n)}_s) ds, \int _0^T h_1(V^{(1)}_s) ds,\ldots ,\int _0^T h_n(V^{(n)}_s) ds\right) ,\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(27)

the log asset price \(S_t\) is normally distributed, i.e.

$$\begin{aligned}&\log (S_T)\Big | \left( V_T^{(1)},\ldots ,V_T^{(n)}, \int _0^T m_1^2(V^{(1)}_s) ds,\ldots ,\int _0^T m_n^2(V^{(n)}_s) ds,\right. \nonumber \\&\quad \left. \int _0^T h_1(V^{(1)}_s) ds,\ldots ,\int _0^T h_n(V^{(n)}_s) ds\right) \nonumber \\&\sim \mathcal {N}\left( \log (S_0)+rT-\frac{1}{2} \int _0^T \sum _{i=1}^{n} m_i^2(V^{(i)}_s) ds+\sum _{i=1}^{n} \rho _i \Big (g_i(V^{(i)}_T)-g_i(V^{(i)}_0)\right. \nonumber \\&\left. -\int _0^T h_i(V^{(i)}_s) ds\Big ),\quad \quad \sum _{i=1}^{n} (1-\rho _i^2)\int _0^T m_i^2(V^{(i)}_s) ds \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(28)

We have also utilized the fact that conditioning on Eq. (27)

$$\begin{aligned} \mathrm {Var}\left( \sum _{i=1}^{n} \sqrt{1-\rho _i^2} \int _0^T m_i(V^{(i)}_s) \,d\bar{Z}_s^{(i)}\right)&=\sum _{i=1}^{n} \mathrm {Var}\left( \sqrt{1-\rho _i^2} \int _0^T m_i(V^{(i)}_s) \,d\bar{Z}_s^{(i)}\right) \\&=\sum _{i=1}^{n} (1-\rho _i^2)\int _0^T m_i^2(V^{(i)}_s)\, ds, \end{aligned}$$

and this is due to the fact that \(\bar{Z}^{(i)}\) are independent of each other.

Remark A.1

Note that the conditional representation in Eq. (28) can be thought of as a multivariate generalization of Eq. (5). Thus we can similarly extend the conditional representation of the density of \(S_T\) as given in Eq. (6), to the multivariate case. Also note that the main results in Sects. 3 and 4 also depend on the representation in Eq. (5), thus their statements can be similarly extended to the case of multivariate volatility factors.

Remark A.2

The density of \(S_T\) can be similarly obtained in this multivariate volatility case, because the volatility factors are independent from each other, i.e. \((V_T^{(i)}, \int _0^T m_1^2(V^{(i)}_s) ds, \int _0^T h_1(V^{(i)}_s) ds)\) is independent from \((V_T^{(j)}, \int _0^T m_1^2(V^{(j)}_s) ds, \int _0^T h_1(V^{(j)}_s) ds)\) for \(i\ne j\). Thus based on Eq. (28), the density of \(S_T\) can be obtained by integrating the normal density against the products of density functions of \((V_T^{(i)}, \int _0^T m_1^2(V^{(i)}_s) ds, \int _0^T h_1(V^{(i)}_s) ds)\) for \(i=1,\ldots ,n\), each of which can be obtained through our exponential measure change technique as illustrated in Sect. 4.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Cui, Z., Nguyen, D. & Park, H. An integral representation of elasticity and sensitivity for stochastic volatility models. Math Finan Econ 12, 249–274 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11579-017-0203-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11579-017-0203-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation