Skip to main content
Log in

Piety, profit and the market in Cairo: a political economy of Islamisation

  • Published:
Contemporary Islam Aims and scope Submit manuscript

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. The fashioning of a religious lifestyle through consumption has taken diverse and elaborate forms including what some scholars have termed “Christian consumerism”. See Thomas (2009).

  2. Muslim lifestyles and identities have become increasingly differentiated in and through contemporary consumption processes and practices. For example, the commercialisation of religious rituals has produced different classes of practising Muslims, distinguished by the class of their hajj (pilgrimage) journeys. Some undertake the “business hajj” (also referred to as al-hajj al-sari’or quick hajj) which guarantees travel and accommodation comfort, a shortened stay and customised rituals. Meanwhile those with limited means undertake the economy class hajj. Both the Islamisation of consumption and the commodification of religious practices have entered into the production of social distinction in religious terms.

  3. I interviewed 45 merchants and workshop proprietors using the snowball method. Three local residents assisted me by arranging introductions to merchants and entrepreneurs.

  4. I use a number of criteria such as capital investment, volume of trade and turnover of goods to determine the size of the business. Based on interviews with merchants and extrapolating from the criteria used to define micro and small businesses, I have determined that a minimum capital investment of LE 200,000 for a stock of goods that goes through a turn-over in a cycle of 3 to 6 months are important criteria in defining middle-size trade. Other criteria include the rental value or real-estate value of the shops and the size of warehouses owned or rented by the merchant. As the majority of my interviews were with wholesalers in El-Moski and Harat al-Yahud, their capital investment and their volume of trade tended to be above this threshold. With regard to workshops, the number of workers is an important criterion in my use of “medium-size”, with eleven being the minimum number of workers for a middle-size establishment.

  5. The conditions of monopoly characterise most sectors of trade and commerce where few importers and merchants control the market for basic goods such as sugar, rice and oil. Manufacturing and imports of intermediate goods are in the hands of a few manufacturers cum merchants who control their sales and distribution (e.g. manufacturing and imports of refrigerators, electric fans, water heaters and television sets). Thus, it could be argued that trade with China contributed to a breakdown of monopoly in the consumer market. However, recent government measures such as the introduction, in June 2010, of quality control certificates for imports from China and the banning of certain Chinese imports such as mobile phones could constrain market competition.

  6. The bulk of the interviews took place in al-Moski market and in Harat-al-Yahud. The merchants traded in children’s toys, men and women’s clothing, light household goods or textiles. Workshop owners specialised in either clothing or jewellery manufacturing. A number of the merchant-wholesalers were importers of goods from China. Others relied on large importers to procure the merchandise they later sold to retailers.

  7. For example, the Moski market trading in manufactured clothes both locally produced and imported includes a large group of merchants from the town of Banga, located in Suhag, an Upper Egypt governorate. Meanwhile, the Hamam el-Talat trade in household electrical goods is associated with the Tawabiyya merchants, originating from al-Tawabiyya village in Qina, another Upper Egypt governorate.

  8. It could be argued that the “full price” which is charged for goods paid on instalment is a marked-up price that includes the equivalent of an estimate of the yield of capital calculated on the basis of the ongoing interest rate. In some sense, it functions in a similar manner to interest charges, serving to compensate for a delayed payment on capital that could be reinvested and potentially bring in further profits.

  9. In addition to the religious credentials used to establish trust, a merchant’s reputation in honouring repayment commitments is integral to the circulation of credit. If a merchant defaults on payments, he risks losing future supplies from other creditors/merchants who operate in the same market.

  10. As noted in the context of Turkey, the interest in social justice and the free market are qualified and informed by the actors’ socio-economic position as owners of medium enterprises who see their economic interests as best protected by free competition and limits on capital accumulation associated with large monopolies. The antagonism is directed at large businesses that benefit from preferential treatment that a wide array of state regulations affords them. There are clear parallels here with the vision presented by the medium entrepreneurs who support the AKP in Turkey (Tuğal 2002: 100).

  11. This ‘Islamic’ department store has now replaced public sector department stores such as Omar Effendi which have been sold to the private sector.

  12. See Elyachar (2005) for a discussion of similar practices by workshop owners.

  13. The signs also indicate the enmeshment of this identity in the global fields of exchange with references to the Chinese provenance of the goods. For example, one shop sign reads “al-Batul for Chinese gold” (al-Batul refers to the Virgin Mary). During my visits to Harat al-Yahud, I noted that along with the use of elaborate lighting on shops to mark the day of launching a new business, shop proprietors hired DJs to play Quranic recitations or Coptic religious lessons that could be heard in the streets.

  14. In Ala al-Aswani’s novel ‘Imarat Ya‘qubian, this is typified in the figure of hajj Azzam who made the seed for his fortune by trading in drugs, but who cultivated all the trappings of piety (al-Aswani 2002). Hajj Azzam’s character is thought to be modelled after the figure of one of the wealthier religious merchants in Cairo who owns a chain of shoe stores and who is a sole agent of a number of international car manufacturers. Azzam’s ostentatious lifestyle, symbolised by living in an opulent house, owning expensive cars and marrying a second wife, is constructed as a confirmation of God’s blessing in conservative religious discourses, while viewed by social critics, both secular and religious, as an indication of a superficial adherence to religion on the part of a social stratum that benefited from the liberalisation of the economy.

  15. See Schielke (2009) for a discussion of different understandings of religion and the ambiguity that arises in articulations of its role in everyday life among young Muslims. Schielke’s (2009: 176) distinction between different registers of religion, in particular between religion as a ‘comprehensive discipline’ as espoused by Salafi-oriented Muslims, and religion as ‘framework of subjectivitiy and action that is neither exclusive nor exhaustive’, as understood by many young Muslims, is similarly suggestive of the different senses of religion that are evoked in everyday life.

References

  • Abd al-Rahman, M. (2004). Divine consumption: Islamic goods in Cairo. Cairo Papers, 27(1&2), 69–78.

    Google Scholar 

  • Adas, E. B. (2006). The making of entrepreneurial Islam and the Islamic spirit of capitalism. Journal for Cultural Research, 10(2), 113–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Al-Aswani, A. (2002). ‘Imarat Ya’qubian [The Yacoubian Building]. Cairo: Maktabit Madbuli.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beckert, J. (2010). How do fields change? The interrelations of institutions, networks, and cognition in the dynamics of markets. Organization Studies, 31(5), 605–627.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biggart, N. W., & Beamish, T. D. (2003). The economic sociology of conventions: habit, custom, practice, and routine in market order. Annual Review of Sociology, 29, 443–464.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deeb, L. (2006). An enchanted modern: Gender and public piety in Shi’i Lebanon. New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deeb, L., & Harb, M. (2007). Sanctioned pleasures: youth, piety and leisure in Beirut. Middle East Report, 245, 12–19.

    Google Scholar 

  • El-Katatney, E. (2008). The business of Islam. Business Today.

  • Elyachar, J. (2005). Markets of dispossession: NGOS, economic development and the state in Egypt. Durham: Duke University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fourcade, M. (2007). Theories of markets and theories of society. American Behavioral Scientist, 50(8), 1015–1034.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gokariksel, B., & Secor, A. J. (2009). New transnational geographies of Islamisation, capitalism and subjectivity: the veiling fashion industry in Turkey. Area, 41(1), 6–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gülalp, H. (2001). Globalization and political Islam: social bases of Turkey’s welfare party. International Journal of Middle East Studies, 33(3), 433–448.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gülalp, H. (2003). Whatever happened to secularization? The multiple Islams in Turkey. The South Atlantic Quarterly, 102(2/3), 381–395.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haenni, P. (2005). L’islam du marché: l’autre révolution conservatrice. Editions du Seuil.

  • Hefner, R. (1998). Multiple modernities: Christianity, Islam, Hinduism in a globalizing world. Annual Review of Anthropology, 27, 83–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ismail, S. (2003). Rethinking Islamist politics: Culture, the State and Islamism. London: I.B. Tauris.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ismail, S. (2007). Islamism, re-Islamisation and the fashioning of Muslim Selves: refiguring the public sphere. Muslim World Journal of Human Rights, 4(1), art 3.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mahmood, S. (2005). Politics of piety. New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marsden, M. (2005). Living Islam: Muslim religious experience in Pakistan’s North West frontier. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mayer, A. E. (1985). Islamic banking and credit policies in the Sadat Era: the social origins of Islamic banking in Egypt. Arab Law Quarterly, 1(1), 32–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Navaro-Yahsin, Y. (2002). The market for identities: Secularism, Islamism, commodities. In D. Kandiyoti & A. Saktanber (Eds.), Fragments of culture: The everyday of modern Turkey (pp. 221–253). New Jersey: Rutgers University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Osella, F., & Osella, C. (2009). Muslim entrepreneurs in public life between India and the gulf: making good and doing good. The Journal of the Royal Anthropological Institute, 15(S1), 202–221.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rudnyckyj, D. (2009a). Spiritual economies: Islam and neoliberalism in contemporary Indonesia. Cultural Anthropology, 24(1), 104–141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rudnyckyj, D. (2009b). Market Islam in Indonesia. The Journal of the Royal Anthropological Institute, 15(S1), 183–201.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schielke, S. (2009). Ambivalent commitments: troubles of morality and aspiration among young Egyptians. Journal of Religion in Africa, 39, 158–185.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schulz, D. (2008). Re-turning to proper Muslim practice: Islamic moral renewal and women’s conflicting assertions of Sunni identity in Urban Mali. Africa Today, 54(4), 21–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Secor, A. (2002). The veil and urban space in Istanbul: women’s dress, mobility and Islamic knowledge. Gender, Place and Culture, 9(1), 5–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sloane, P. (1999). Islam, modernity and entrepreneurship among the Malays. London: St. Martin’s Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sloane, P. (2011). Working in the Islamic economy: Sharia-ization and the Malaysian workplace. Sojourn: Journal of Social Issues in Southeast Asia, 26(2), 304–334.

    Google Scholar 

  • Starrett, G. (1995). The political economy of religious commodities in Cairo. American Anthropologist, 97(1), 51–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomas, P. (2009). Selling God/saving souls: religious commodities, spiritual markets and the media. Global Media and Communication, 5(1), 57–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tuğal, C. (2002). Islamism in Turkey: beyond instrument and meaning. Economy and Society, 31(1), 85–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Salwa Ismail.

Additional information

This work was supported by the Economic and Social Research Council (ESRC) (Res-062-23-2283). An earlier version of this article was presented to the workshop on “What makes a good Muslim?” Helsinki, April 14–16, 2010.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Ismail, S. Piety, profit and the market in Cairo: a political economy of Islamisation. Cont Islam 7, 107–128 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11562-013-0249-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11562-013-0249-8

Keywords

Navigation